- Original Article
- Open access
- Published: 24 October 2020

Competition and microfinance institutions’ performance: evidence from India
- Hailu Abebe Wondirad 1
International Journal of Corporate Social Responsibility volume 5 , Article number: 6 ( 2020 ) Cite this article
14k Accesses
7 Citations
Metrics details
This paper empirically examines whether competition (measured by using the new measure of competition, the Boone Indicator) moderates the relationship between Microfinance Institutions’ (MFIs) social and financial performances using data from 183 Indian MFIs over the period 2005–2014.
The findings indicate that MFIs’ social and financial performances have a positive significant relationship. Moreover, the form of the relationship is both lead-lag and cotemporal. The Indian microfinance market was very competitive over the period 2005–2014. The empirical findings show that competition positively moderates the relationship between MFIs’ social and financial performances. More precisely, the empirical analysis provides evidence that the association between MFIs’ depth of outreach and operational self-sufficiency is conditional upon competition. These results suggest that in a competitive market, the more MFI deepen their depth of outreach, the higher contribution it has to their operational self-sufficiency.
Introduction
Microfinance is the provision of financial service to the poor and low-income people (Mersland, 2011 ). These financial services include savings, credit, insurance, and payment services (Ledgerwood, 1999 ). Microfinance Institutions (henceforth, MFIs) have unique features (i.e. in the form of product or service types, and lending methodologies) that distinguish them from formal banking institutions (Quayes, 2012 ). MFIs are created to fill the market segment that has long been unveiled by the conventional banking sector (Vanroose & D’Espallier, 2013 ).
In the recent decade, the Microfinance industry has been growing rapidly in developing countries (Assefa, Hermes, & Meesters, 2013 ; Kar, 2016 ), and has gotten high recognitions from international actors, donors, and governments (Olsen, 2010 ). The assets of the industry increased from 4 billion to 7 billion from 2006 to 2008 (Littlefield & Kneiding, 2009 ) and demonstrated a growth rate of 25% per year from 2004 to 2008 (Servet, 2011 ). The total clients served by the sector were also reached over 205.3 million in 2012 (Maes & Reed, 2012 ).
The increasing inflow of investment into microfinance is partly because the international community believes MFIs have an institutional foundation that fosters local economic development, creates jobs and empowers women (Gutierrez-Nieto, Serrano-Cinca, & Molinero, 2007 ). Commercialization, accompanied by a huge flow of investment, is the main drivers of microfinance’s evolution and makes it the hub of the potential business opportunity that spurring many institutions to change their ownership from not-for-profit to for-profit (eg. Bancosol Bolivia, Equity in Kenya, ACLEDA in Cambodia, SKS Microfinance in India, and Compartamos in Mexico) (Servet, 2011 ). But studies have been presented that microfinance is not drifted from their mission of serving the low-income people (Mersland & Strøm, 2010 ).
Although MFIs are propagating as banks for the poor, some MFIs address wealthier clients and profitable business segments. MFIs business model is different in terms of ownership, lending methodology, portfolio size, goals, and target market. The impact of the growing trend of commercialization has recently been part of microfinance study (for example Assefa et al., 2013 ; Cull, Demirgüç-Kunt, & Morduch, 2011 ; Fombrun, Gardberg, & Barnett, 2000 ; Freeman, 2010 ; Woller, 2002 ) Most of these studies have documented both positive and negative effects of competition on MFI’s performance or operation in general. The claim of mission drift is also emanating from the exigent debate of commercialization and MFIs’ mission. The root of the debate is that when competition increased, MFIs may shrink from their social mission and then starts striving for financial returns. Altogether, in line with mission drift claims, competition may moderate the association between social and financial performance. Therefore, to prove the existence of this fact, this paper examines the effect of competition on the relationship between social and financial performance by focusing on Indian MFIs.
This paper is organized as follows: In Section 2, the statement of the problem is discussed. Section 3 highlights the microfinance practices of India. Section 4 presents a literature review of the study. In section 5, the methodology and data of the paper are discussed. Section 6 describes the analysis of the results. Section 7 presents conclusions along with some recommendations. Finally, in section 8 of this paper, the practical implication(s) for MFIsare discussed.
Statement of the problem
Because of the lack of infrastructure and smaller portfolio sizes, providing financial services to the unbanked poor people, are very expensive and challenging. As a result, the financial institution serving this segment of the population is considered as socially motivated MFI and has defined social goals. However, whether MFIs emphasize on social aspects or financial aspects has been part of a continuing debate (Conning, 1999 ). In a competitive environment, being a socially responsible institution has a financial cost which in turn impends financial performance (Fombrun et al., 2000 ; Freeman, 2010 ). Firms participating in social development activities faced lower stock value as compared to the average (Vance, 2011 ), and then experienced lower financial performance relative to competitors in the industry (Klein & Dawar, 2004 ). In line with this, Cull, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Morduch ( 2008 ) and Hermes, Lensink, and Meesters ( 2011 ) find a trade-off relationship between financial sustainability and outreach.
On the contrary, the firm’s participation in social development activities helps to retain customers and increases sales volume where positively contributed to financial performance (Ruf, Muralidhar, Brown, Janney, & Paul, 2001 ). In microfinance, Montgomery and Weiss ( 2011 ), and Quayes ( 2012 ) find evidence that supports this theory; in such a way that outreach has a positive significant relationship with financial performance.
Recently, a double bottom line approach Footnote 1 has become popular in microfinance. MFIs have also been started pursuing a balance between social and financial performance (Ngo, 2015 ). Rating organizations have already started rating MFIs based on the ability to pursue their double bottom line objectives (Gutiérrez-Nieto, Serrano-Cinca, & Molinero, 2009 ). On top of that, the rapid evolution of Microfinance and its commercialization induced intense competition (Assefa et al., 2013 ; Woller, 2002 ). As competition increased, dealing with double bottom line objectives and achieving it simultaneously requires a strategic decision that reconciles the defined mission, and also be challenging. Consequently, increasing competition creates frustration that may compromise the MFIs’ social mission. It has been witnessed that commercialized MFIs provide four times larger loans, then non-commercialized MFIs (Cull et al., 2011 ), which shows that they might have abandoned their marginalized borrowers. Through increasing clients’ loan burden and deteriorating repayment performance, the competition also threatens MFIs’ financial performance (Assefa et al., 2013 ).
Theoretically, there are two different views. On the one hand, the competition-fragility theory that states, lack of competition in the market develop rent-seeking behaviors among firms (Boyd & De Nicolo, 2005 ). In such a market, MFIs are price setter rather than price takers. Although this theory points out that clients became a victim of the rent-seeking behavior of MFIs, the state of mission drift could not be determined. On the other hand, the competition-stability theory views firms as price takers (Beck, 2008 ). The market is offering an affordable price to customers. According to this theory, the competition allows clients to have strong barraging power on the price of a loan and to get a required loan amount. However, the sustainability of MFIs doesn’t exactly define. Competition-fragility theory has a profit motive, whereas, competition-stability theory recognized financial accesses at an affordable price. Thus, theories are not rationalized the impacts of competition on the relationship between MFIs’ social and financial performance. Altogether, in the financial market where there is a high competition, the relationship between social and financial performances of microfinance institutions is inferred.
Thus, from the above discussion, it can be thought out that in a highly competitive market, MFI focuses on a social mission that may experience lower financial performance or vice-versa. It means competition may influence the relationship between social and financial performance. In microfinance, understanding the characteristics of this market force (competition) and responding accordingly to it is vital to offer financial service permanently to the poor people and keep MFIs’ sustainability in the long run (Vogelgesang, 2003 ).
Although some studies examined the effect of competition on MFIs’ performance, the moderating effect of competition on the link between social and financial performances hasn’t been studied. Therefore, by considering these gaps, this study tried to analyze the following two research questions:
What is the relationship between MFIs’ social and financial performance?
Does competition has a moderating effect on the relationship between MFIs’ social and financial performance?
The overall objective of this research is to analyze the moderating effect of competition on the relationship between MFIs’ social and financial performance. Specifically, the research aims to identify the effect of competition on the link between depth and breadth of outreach, and Operational Self-Sufficiency (OSS) and Return on Asset (ROA) links.
Microfinance in India
The development and features of the Indian microfinance sector are discussed below. Microfinance has long been considered as instruments to provide financial services to the marginalized poor segment of the population in India.
The history of microfinance in India goes back to the 1970s when the first form of microfinance, Self Employed Women’s Association (SEWA), has established to provide financial services to poor women. In 1969 industrialization policy of India shifted its attention towards designing a new lending approach to the agricultural sector and rural poor (Burgess & Pande, 2003 .) This brought a downfall to informal credit operated by moneylenders, which accounts for more than half of the household credit in the 1970s (Shah, Rao, & Shankar, 2007 ). In early 19th India has long been recognized as a country where a large number of unbanked rural poor people found. To change this by providing access to finance to the remotely found rural poor people, microfinance is considered as a promising instrument to bring sustainable rural development.
Therefore, in the 1970s and 1980s, the government has designed the Integrated Rural Development Program (IRDP) with the mission to subsidized agricultural credit and bring livelihood improvement (Taylor, 2001 ). This program has been an opportunity for rural poor to experience the formal financial sector. Later, in 1972, the Self-Employed Women’s Association of India (SEWA) established and started providing financial services and led a path for the establishment of SEWA Bank (Datta, 2003 ).
After a decade of its first movement, another form of microfinance, Self Help Groups (SHGs) has emerged in India and became popular still now. Then, Non-Governmental Organizations (NGOs) and other community development institutions have been joined the industry and became major players in the sector.
Generally, the historical evolution of microfinance growth in India has divided into two stages. The first stage was the one motivated and supported by NGOs and other development organizations by offering micro-credit services. The second phase considered as a “microfinance movement” where formal financial firms have entered into the microfinance market to provide financial services to the unbanked poor people. In the “microfinance movement” the forms or legal status of institutions and their financial products and services have diversified. It is also considered as the transformation from mere credit age to all-rounded financial services age. Currently, Commercial Bank, Non-Bank Financial Institutions (NBFI), Rural Bank, Credit Union, and NGOs are the well-known forms of microfinance institutions operating in India that providing credit, saving, remittance, financial training (Guha, 2007 ). The Indian microfinance sector is dominated by NBFIs, has an 80% market share (Etzensperger, 2013 ).
As indicated above the Indian microfinance operation has been leading by the different forms of institutions. However, their services delivery model can be categorized into two main delivery models: SHG and MFI model. The latter is the most dominant model in the country. The MFI model provides a range of lending methodologies such as joint liability groups, Grameen, and individual banking.
From 2005 to 2010, the Indian microfinance industry has strongly been grown (Kar, 2016 ). The clients’ demand for the loan and huge flow of investment are the diver factors of the high growth of the industry. However, later, an unprecedented crisis affected the promising growth of the Indian microfinance industry.
The crisis happened in Andhra Pradesh, a southern state of India. Although Andhra Pradesh was the place where the crisis began before the watershed the state was considered as the hub of microfinance, and many NGO driven MFIs where found. In 2006 when the sector entered into crisis, in Krishna district of Andhra Pradesh, the borrowers turned into demonstration and violent to claim back their fixed asset seized as collateral. In Andhra Pradesh, as compared to other regions, averagely a household owe loans from nine MFIs (India Report 2010). Because this state placed the sector as a priority sector to tackle poverty and received support from the World Bank, the sector has been highly expanded, and overlapping became the main feature of Indian MFIs (Taylor, 2001 ). Until recently, because of the availability of loans from competitive sources, the sector represents a low repayment rate.
The crisis exacerbate when around 200 suicides were linked to microfinance institutions. Due to the crisis, the repayment rate of the sector dropped down to 10%. On top of that, a very high default rate, unethical loan collection practices, and high-interest rate (25% -40%) become the characteristics of the Indian microfinance sector (Ghate, 2007 and Sharma, 2006 ). By the time, 40% of the residents of the state of Andhra Pradesh had MFIs’ loan (Mader, 2013 ). Altogether puts 82% of households of the district indebted. Consequently, the government has taken action by closing around 50 MFIs (Mader, 2013 ).
After the crisis the microfinance industry of India continued to demonstrate high growth. However, commercialization and aggressive expansion of MFIs intensify the competition in the sector. The crisis and the entrance of MFIs into the stock market are considered as the main driver of commercialization in the Indian microfinance sector.
Following Compartamos (Mexican MFI), Indian MFI, SKS entered into the initial public offering and raised around $350 million. Due to the large commercial fund injected into the sector, the loan portfolio has been substantially increased and exacerbate the trend of commercialization.
On the other hand, the neo-liberal economic reform and commercial funding, have been taking as another pushing factor of commercialization in the microfinance sector of India (Bateman, 2010 ; Taylor, 2001 and Wichterich, 2012 ). Commercial funding affects MFIs to change their source of funds from loans to share capital by entering into the capital market (Mader, 2013 ; Taylor, 2001 ).
Moreover, the legal framework of the Indian microfinance sector is also responsible for the high growth of the commercialization of microfinance. In India, only formal financial Institutions are allowed to raise equity capital and mobilize public deposits. Hence, NGOs, SHGs, and other semi-formal money lenders forced to change their legal status into NBFIs and banks which then leads to shifting from their social mission to finance-oriented (Guha, 2013 ).
As evidenced above, commercialization becomes the main feature of the Indian microfinance sector. This commercialization leads to competition and market saturation (Mader, 2013 ). Competition, in turn, causes over-indebtedness in the sector. Later in 2010, the government of India introduced interest caps. Nowadays, the microfinance market of India undergone trough tight control and scrutiny. The growing trend of commercialization is the main reason for strict regulation.
As the above discussion shows, in its early stage of development, the main mission of Indian microfinance is fighting poverty through outreach. In this regard, although there has been an imbalance across the regions in India, MFIs have been demonstrating high growth of outreach in the sector.
Moreover, like the main notion of microfinance, it is clear that Indian MFIs have double bottom line objectives, MFIs’ social outreach, and financial sustainability (Morduch, 1999 ). Although some MFIs have been striving to achieve a balance between social and financial performance, competition makes it very challenging and sometimes lead to mission drift (Ngo, 2015 ).
However, now the rapid growth of commercialization in the Indian microfinance sector and competition pushes MFIs to change their social mission of providing access to finance for the unbanked segment of the population to profit-seeking institutions (Guha, 2013 ). In a competitive microfinance sector, achieving the double bottom line objectives is very challenging (Cull et al., 2011 ). Consequently, increasing competition creates frustration of poor financial performance that spurring MFIs to compromise their social mission. It has been witnessed that commercialized Indian MFIs provide larger loans, then non-commercialized MFIs (Taylor, 2001 and Wichterich, 2012 ) which shows that they might shift from their social mission.
Thus, whether market competition causes a shift in MFIs’ mission needs to be investigated. In a competitive market, do MFIs shift from their social mission towards financial objectives? is needs to be answered. Consequently, the objective of this paper is to examine whether competition has a moderating effect on the relationship between MFIs’ social mission and financial performance.
Literature review
In this section, a review of the literature on MFIs’ performance and competition are provided. First, both theoretical and empirical evidence on the relationship between social and financial performance are discussed. Second, the effect of competition on MFIs’ performance is reviewed. Finally, theories and literature that show the moderation effects of competition are discussed.
Social and financial performance: theoretical review
In the 1970s System theory was broken up the closed-lope strategies of institutions. According to Ackoff ( 1970 ) system theory advocates that all partners within the network are incorporated in organizational decision-making and problem-solving. From a System theory point of view, the optimal strategy is the one that able to combine partners’ interests in such that the firm’s strategy is optimal for the network. Based on this theory, given the strategy of the partners, to formulate an optimal business approach, the organization is considering the mutual benefits of all partners in the network of the organization. Concerning system theory, stakeholder theory has brought to incorporate social issues into the business model of firms.
Stakeholder theory states that socially responsible institutions have better financial performance (Freeman, 2010 ). Stakeholder theory helps to understand how incorporating the interests of stakeholder (customers) to influence the financial performance of the MFIs. It means it lays a foundation for the possible relationship between social and financial performance. This is because the domain of stakeholder theory thought out that satisfying the interest of customers has a positive direct contribution towards MFIs’ profitability. Contextually, MFIs are expected to fulfill their social objective by offering financial services that meet the interest of poor or low-income people. This theory asserts that stakeholders should involve in the decision-making process of the organization and institutions have to consider the meeting of their need as an unavoidable cost of doing business (Freeman, 2010 ). In the stakeholder theory perspective, sustainability is based on the organization’s understanding of the external environment and responds to those affected by its strategies. Stakeholder theory serves as a framework to examine the relationship between social and financial performance (Ruf et al., 2001 ) and has also supported by several empirical pieces of evidence. In line with stakeholder theory, studies found a positive relationship between social and financial performance.
Ruf et al. ( 2001 ) investigate the relationship between corporate social and financial performances from a stakeholder theory perspective. The result of their analysis suggests that improvement in social performance has both immediate and continuing impact on financial performance. This implies that meeting stakeholders’ interests (achieving the social mission) provide a competitive advantage to retain market share and enhance profitability in the long run. Ribstein ( 2005 ) supports this view by arguing that incorporating corporate social responsibility builds strong stakeholder loyalty which in turn enhances financial performance. Moreover, achieving a social mission reduce unsystematic risks (Orlitzky & Benjamin, 2001 ) and determine competitive advantage (Turban and Greening, 1996 ). Similarly, others have also found constant results in support of stakeholder theory (e.g. Cornell & Shapiro, 1987 ; Preston & O'bannon, 1997 ; Simpson & Kohers, 2002 ). The evidence seems to support the view that developing favorable social performance (positive public image, good reputation, stakeholder satisfaction, etc.) results in promising financial performance.
Social and financial performance’s relationship: empirical review
Starting from the early development stage of microfinance, there is an ongoing debate between two groups which is referred to as the “Welfarists” and “institutionalists” (Hudon, 2011 ). Based on the Welfarists’ doctrine, microfinance is a bank that provides financial services to the poor, and designed as a development tool to fight against poverty (Woller, 2002 ). Whereas, institutionalists argue that to provide permanent financial services without subsidy, MFIs have to focus on self-sustainability (Robinson, 2001 ). Since then, the Microfinance industry is growing and getting diversified in the forms of product and services, ownership status, lending methodology, size, and goals. Of these diverse characteristics, MFIs have the double bottom line objective of social outreach and financial sustainability (Morduch, 1999 ). The nature of a relationship between MFIs’ social mission and sustainability and whether they can pursue their social mission and become sustainable at the same time is part of the debates in microfinance literature for decades.
In microfinance literature, studies have been conducted to find out the nature of the relationship between social and financial performance and remain debatable. One group of scholars argues that there is a trade-off relationship between social and financial performance (e.g. Conning, 1999 ; Cull et al., 2008 ; D’Espallier, Goedecke, Hudon, & Mersland, 2017 ; Hermes et al., 2011 ; Navajas, Schreiner, Meyer, Gonzalez-Vega, & Rodriguez-Meza, 2000 ; Schreiner, 2002 ). On the other strand, scholars find that a positive complementary relationship exists between self-sustainability and outreach (e.g. Adhikary & Papachristou, 2014 ; Montgomery & Weiss, 2011 ; Quayes, 2012 ). Moreover, some findings show no or neutral relationship (e.g. Bassem, 2015 ; Lebovics, Hermes, & Hudon, 2016 ). In the following section, evidence that supports both positive and trade-off relationships are discussed. First, empirical evidence that supports positive association will present, and then trade-off follows.
Complementary (positive) relationship
More recently, Adhikary and Papachristou ( 2014 ) find that MFIs’ sustainability and outreach are positively correlated and have a complementary relationship. They argue that both depth and breadth of outreach are positively related to profitability (Return on Asset) and efficiency (cost per borrower) of MFIs. Furthermore, according to them, as compared to the better-off clients, serving the poorest segment of the population has lower credit risk; the smaller the loan size (depth of outreach) the lowest credit risk.
Montgomery and Weiss ( 2011 ), Quayes ( 2012 ) also suggest that MFIs are undertaking and achieving both financial and social missions concurrently. Likewise, social performance helps to develop mutual trust and increase customer participation, which in turn reduces delinquency and operating costs (Lapenu, 2007 ).
Trade-off (negative) relationship
Cull et al. ( 2008 ) argue that higher profitability is associated with low depth of outreach. Implies that MFI strives for profitability abandons the poor segment of the population from its portfolio. Hence, the trade-off relationship exists between MFI efficiency (financial performance) and serving low-income people (outreach) (Gonzalez, 2010 ; Maîtrot, 2019 ). Besides, small loan sizes and high transaction costs of serving the poorest are the immediate reasons for the MFIs’ high-interest rate (Mersland & Strøm, 2010 ; Morduch, 2000 ; Rosenberg, Gonzalez, & Narain, 2009 ). But, charging a high loan rate on a poor’s portfolio to cover high operating costs emanates from doing a transaction with them has taken as a trade-off between outreach and financial performance (Schreiner, 2002 ). So, these authors claim that high transaction costs associated with small loan size impend effort of maximizing depth outreach without sacrificing financial stability.
Consistent with the above findings, because of the lack of collateral and high risks associated with poor clients, an MFI targets poor individual incur high operational costs, and shows the trade-off between social and financial performance (Bédécarrats, Baur, & Lapenu, 2012 ; Nawaz & Iqbal, 2015 ). Altogether, Bédécarrats, Baur, and Lapenu ( 2012 ) conclude that MFIs attain social and financial performance in both trade-off and synergy. Additionally, Morduch ( 2000 ) also supports these views by arguing that a trade-off relationship exists between profitability and outreach.
Ngo ( 2015 ) also finds strong empirical evidence for a trade-off relationship between financial performance and outreach. He argues that there is a threshold level for a trade-off to happen in which beyond this threshold level MFI maximizes their financial performance at the expense of the social mission. The above empirical evidence is also supported by other findings. For instance, Hermes et al. ( 2011 ) reveal a trade-off relationship between efficiency and outreach, were undertaking a social mission threatens MFI’s cost efficiency.
Nevertheless, some evidences exposed neither a trade-off nor a complementary relationship. Recently, Lebovics et al. ( 2016 ) find that Vietnamese’s MFIs are both social and financially efficient, but neither trade-off nor synergy association exists between social outreach and financial sustainability. They assert that cost efficiency is indirectly correlated with the depth of outreach which implies targeting low-income people threatens efficiency. Other findings also support the above evidence. For instance, Bassem ( 2015 ) find a neutral relationship. Thus, based on the above empirical evidences, it can be thought out that, in microfinance, the trade-off between social and financial performances have demonstrated. So, a trade-off relationship is also expected.
Although the theoretical discussion consistently supports a positive relationship, the empirical findings in section 4.2.1 and 4.2.2 on the relationship between social and financial performance are mixed. Consequently, this paper proposed in both negative and positive hypotheses that hypothesize as:
Hypothesis 1: social performance has a positive/negative significant effect on financial performance
- Competition
Competition measures
Banking works of literature have been forwarded to different measures of Competition. Those measures are broadly classified into two paradigms, Structural Conduct Performance (SCP) and the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) paradigms. SCP paradigm measures competition based on market structure and assumes that the competition is lower in a concentrated market, but the profit is higher. Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) is one of the SCP technique (Van Leuvensteijn, Bikker, van Rixtel, & Sørensen, 2011 ).
HHI value ranges from 0 to 1. The value closer to 0 indicates high competition, whereas 1 indicates a monopoly structure. However, HHI is criticized by the fact that it doesn’t take into account competitive behavior and bank’s ownership, and its assumption also lacks theoretical support (Coccorese, 2009 ; Lau, 1982 ).
A New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) approach is a nonstructural measure whereby competition is measured through estimating parameters that reflect the firm’s competitive behavior. Panzar and Rosse statistics and the Lerner index are categorized under this approach. These indexes estimate firms’ market competitive power by considering a bank or firm as an independent decision-making entity. H-statistics estimates competition parameters based on the relationship between the price of inputs and equilibrium revenue. It ranges from 0 to 1, 1 represents a perfect competition, market, and H = 0 represents monopoly competition (Panzar & Rosse, 1987 ).
Learner Index is another most widely used measure of competition. In Learner Index, the firm’s market power is estimated using its price (P) and marginal cost (MC), (P-MC) /MC. When the value of the Lerner index closes to zero, it shows the presence of intense competition, whereas when PMC > 0, competition is lower. Amir ( 2003 ) asserts that the learner index lacks a theoretical foundation and not a robust indicator.
Recently, Boone ( 2008 ) introduced a new measure of competition, Boone Indicator. Boone indicator works on the assumption that in a competitive market efficient firm always performs better than the inefficient one. The Boone indicator estimates competition between firms by considering the association of profit and marginal cost. Thus, according to Boone Indicator, in a competitive market inefficient firms lost their profit and market share.
The new approach to measure competition has the advantage of handling MFIs’ efficiency and market share relationship and allows them to easily measuring competition on the specific product-market (van Leuvensteijn et al., 2011 ). The details of the Boone Indicator presented in part 5.
Competition and MFIs’ performance
Vogelgesang ( 2003 ) finds twofold of effects between competition and MFIs; positive and negative. On one hand, high competition improves repayment behavior and induces clients to pay on time. On the other hand, competition increases the supply of loan which in turn creates a loan burden and then leads to defeat. Schicks and Rosenberg ( 2011 ) share Vogelgesang’s second thought by arguing that competition creates over-indebtedness which increase delinquency rate and impend the sustainability of MFIs.
McIntosh and Wydick ( 2005 ) analyze the impact of competition on clients’ behavior and the results show that raising competition worsens delinquency rates. However, they also find that increased competition doesn’t change the dropout rates and loan amount. According to them, the entrance of new competing lender leads to multiple loan taking which in turn worsen repayment performance and reduced saving level of borrowers. In a later study, McIntosh, Janvry, and Sadoulet ( 2005 ) examined the effect of competition on the performance of MFIs, which suggests that competition creates over-indebtedness and negative externalities. They find that competition increases asymmetric information between competing MFIs which negative influences both impatient and patient borrowers. Likewise, competition increases the supply of loans in the microfinance market and erodes the power of social capital to serve as collateral (Villas-Boas & Schmidt-Mohr, 1999 ).
Assefa et al. ( 2013 ) suggest that competition has a negative relationship with outreach, which leads to conservative lending activities. On the other hand, they argue that competition has a positive significant effect on loan repayment which means leads to lower repayment rate, in turn, brings to more loans at risk and writes off. But, they conclude that competition negatively correlates with MFIs’ financial performance. Olsen ( 2010 ) also confirms the negative relationship between competition and outreach.
As indicated above, competition leads to multiple loans taking which exacerbate the default rate and other indebtedness. However, Guha and Chowdhury ( 2014 ) argue that borrowing from multiple sources threatens the real impacts of MFIs in their society. They claim that in double-dipping situations MFIs are targeting poor people, not crowding out. Competition lowers interest rates, improves the quality of service, and enhances innovation in microfinance (Porteous, 2006 ). It can be contended that competition in microfinance has both positive and negative effects on MFIs’ social and financial performances. Motta ( 2004 ) and Navajas, Conning, and Gonzalez-Vega ( 2003 ) also suggest that competition reduces operating costs and the price of a loan, and foster innovation among MFIs.
Moderating effect of competition
Theoretical background.
There are two theories of competition, competition-stability, and competition-fragility. The competition-stability theory is a competition theory that sees competition as a market stability force (Beck, 2008 ). Whereas, competition-fragility is a theory favors market concentration by assuming competition as a negative force towards the firm’s performance (Carletti & Hartmann, 2002 ).
From the competition-fragility theory point of view, lack of competition in the market develops rent-seeking behaviors among firms (Boyd & De Nicolo, 2005 ). In such a market, MFIs are price setter rather than price takers. It creates a favorable environment for MFIs to increase prices up to the level that allows them to generate a large sum of profit (Bateman, 2010 ; Helms, 2004 ; Rosenberg et al., 2009 ). Due to this, borrowers bear all the risks to borrow money at a high loan price. Clients became a victim of the rent-seeking behavior of MFIs. It puts them in a higher loan burden and increases the probability of borrower strategic default. On such occasions, credit could appear as an obstacle rather than absorbing the risks of vulnerable poor borrowers.
On top of that, although charging higher interest rate increase MFIs’ profit, it doesn’t target the reality of poor borrowers. It means it is not in line with the very objective of MFI, poverty minimization. From these discussions, it seems that competition-fragility or concentration-stability theory supports that market concentration increases firms’ profit but has a negative contribution to their social performance. In the absence of competition, there is a trade-off between social and financial performances. Therefore, competition negatively moderates the relationship between social and financial performance.
On the contrary, the competition-stability theory views firms as price takers. The market is offering an affordable price to customers. Charging a reasonable price prevent the strategic defeat of the MFIs, thus keep their sustainability. As indicated above in the case of collusion, charging hefty interest rate lowers borrowers’ repayment rate that in turn leads to bankruptcy. According to the competition-stability theory, the competition allows clients to have strong barraging power on the price of a loan and to get a required loan amount at an affordable price. These enhance the repayment performance of borrowers and so, the bank could have sustainable financial performance. Moreover, competition fosters innovation to offer products or services that tailored to the demand of the clients. Accordingly, the financial market offers a reasonable price for each segment of the population and then outreach could be maximized. Hence, competition positively moderates the relationship between social and financial performance.
Empirical background
In a competitive environment, being a socially responsible institution has a financial cost, which hurts the financial performance (Barnett & Salomon, 2012 ; Fombrun et al., 2000 ; Friedman, 1970 ). Organizations participating in social development activities faced lower stock value as compared to the average and experience lower financial performance relative to competitors in the industry (Vance, 2011 ). If MFIs involved in the social mission, competition may threaten their financial performance. This is due to the additional costs of undertaking social activities.
In the less competitive market, MFIs serve not only low-income people but also unbanked wealthier clients (Vanroose & D’Espallier, 2013 ). Serving the better of clients represents a larger loan size and also profitable (Bateman, 2010 ). Indeed, providing larger loan size doesn’t mean that the MFIs are not in line with their social objectives of serving a marginalized segment of the population, rather they are meeting their defined purpose trough cross-subsidization (Armendáriz & Szafarz, 2009 ). Additionally, Vanroose and D’Espallier ( 2013 ) argue that MFIs reach a large number of people in a place where there is a less competitive market and also demonstrate good financial performance and sustainability.
On the other hand, in countries where there is high competition in the microfinance or banking sector, MFIs forced to go to the lower segment of the population (Cull et al., 2011 ; Vanroose & D’Espallier, 2013 ). These MFIs have a deep depth of outreach through offering smaller loan sizes, but the Lower breadth of outreach. Besides, in a competitive market, MFIs obliged to decrease the interest rate to survive and compete in the market, which exacerbates the situation by unable to cover their operational costs. Though these MFIs are keeping their social mission of serving poor people by providing smaller loan sizes, their financial performance and sustainability are in danger because of significant transaction costs emanated from offering smaller loan sizes (Khanam, Parvin, Mohiuddin, Hoque, & Su, 2018 ; Mersland & Strøm, 2009 ). It can be thought out that when competition introduced in the market, social and financial performances’ link has affected.
When competition increased, to attract both social and financially oriented stakeholders and investors, firms have to focus on increasing financial performance and at the same time investing in community development projects (Beisland, D’Espallier, & Mersland, 2019 ; Kanwal, Khanam, Nasreen, & Hameed, 2013 ).
Arguably, the analysis of theoretical and empirical evidence suggests that competition influences the relationship between MFIs’ financial and social performances either positively or negatively. It implies that the strength and form of the relationship between social and financial performance may depend on the value or level of competition. In these senses, it can be hypothesized that;
Hypothesis 2: competition has a positive or negative moderating effect on the relationship between social and financial performance ( Fig. 1 Conceptual Framework of the Study Full size image Fig. 1 ) .
Methodology and data
This section provides a discussion on competition measures, model specifications, and estimation methods. Additionally, the source and detail descriptions of the data are also briefly presented.
Competition measures: Boone indictor
As indicated in chapter two, this paper uses the new measure of competition which is Boone Indicator. Boone indicator is calculated by using the following profit function that measures competition in the market (Boone, 2008 ).
Where π it stands the profit of MFI i at year t which is proxied by Return on Asset (ROA), MC it represents the marginal cost of MFI i at year t, β is Boone indicator and \( {\mathcal{E}}_{\mathrm{it}} \) is the error term. Since the Boone indicator is based on the negative relationship between profit and cost, a negative coefficient value of β (β < 0) is expected. A higher negative value of β indicates the presence of strong competition in the microfinance market, whereas a positive value of β shows the existence of collusion (Van Leuvensteijn et al., 2011 ).
Equation 1 is used to measure the aggregate competition at the microfinance level. So, to capture the development of competition over the year, time dummies ( d t for each year ) are added in the above equation which gives Eq. 2 below.
Additionally, obtaining the value of the Boone coefficient in Eq. 2 requires MC of MFI i at time t. but MC is not measured directly, following Van Leuvensteijn et al. ( 2011 ), a translog of cost function uses to estimates MC of MFI i at year t. Therefore, the cost function in Eq. 3 is applied to estimate parameters which are used to obtain MC it .
Where TC it stands for the total cost, (the sum of financial costs, labor costs, and administration costs) of MFI i at year t, q it is an output of MFI i at year t which is proxied by gross loan portfolio, Footnote 2 W it represents the three input costs Footnote 3 (cost of labor, cost of capital, and cost of fund) of MFI i at time t. The ratio of personnel expense to total assets, the ratio of financial expenses to total assets, and the ratio of administrative expenses to total assets are used as a proxy to measure the cost of labor, cost of fund, and cost of capital respectively.
In the above translog cost function, the input prices are linearly homogeneous (Delis, Iosifidi, & Tsionas, 2014 ). Linear homogeneity assumes that total cost is the result of the three input prices. Thus, following linear homogeneity restrictions imposed on the translog cost function.
\( {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}\sum \limits_{j-1}^3{\alpha}_j=1\dots \dots \dots \dots ..\mathrm{1}\ \sum \limits_{j=1}^3{\delta}_{j+1}=0\dots \dots \dots \dots \dots 2\\ {}\sum \limits_{j=1}^3\sum \limits_{k=1}^3{\alpha}_{jk}\dots \dots \dots \dots \dots \dots \dots \dots \dots \dots .3\end{array}} \)
MC as a first derivative of the cost function, Eq. 3 .
Where MC it is the marginal cost of MFI i at time t, TC it is the total cost of MFI i at time t, q it is output (gross loan portfolio) and W it represents inputs price (cost of labor, cost of capital and cost of fund) of MFI i at time t. the value of MC it obtains by substituting the parameters estimated using the translog cost function in Eq. 2 .
MFIs’ performance measures
Social performance and competition are independent variables of the study. According to Rosenberg et al. ( 2009 ), social performance is the social impact of MFIs in providing financial service to low-income people. The social performance was measured by using depth of outreach which is gaged through depth (average outstanding loan to GNI per capita) and breadth of outreach (active number of borrowers).
Financial performance is the ability to cover all operating costs from operating income (Rosenberg et al., 2009 ), measured by Return on Asset (ROA), Return on Equity (ROE) and Operational Self-Sufficiency (OSS). Control variables are MFI size, MFI age, and donation. The linear regression model for financial and social performance variables are indicated below in Eq. 4 , and the moderating effect of competition represented by Eq. 5 (Table 1 ).
The depth and breadth of outreaches are the two most known measures of the social performance of MFIs. As one of the social performance indicators, depth of outreach refers to the type and poverty level of clients served by MFIs. The breadth of outreach refers to the number of active clients served by MFIs which indicates their scale of operations (Rosenberg et al., 2009 ). The most common proxies used to measure the depth and breadth of outreaches are average outstanding loan (gross loan portfolio to the active number of clients) as a percentage of per capita Gross National Income (GNI) and the logarithm of the number of active clients served respectvlly (Assefa et al., 2013 ; Cull et al., 2009 ; Hermes et al. 2011 ; Rosenberg et al., 2009 ).
Return on Asset (ROA), and Operational Self Sufficiency (OSS) are used to measure MFIs’ financial performance. ROA measures the MFIs’ ability to use its resources profitably. ROA calculates by dividing net operating income by average assets. OSS reflects the MFIs’ ability to cover all expenses through income generated from operational activities and calculates by dividing operating income by total expense.
The Boone indicator is used to measure competition based on the assumption that in a competitive market efficient firm always performs better than the inefficient one. It estimates competition between firms by considering the association of profit and marginal cost. Thus, according to Boone Indicator, in a competitive market inefficient firms lost their profit and market share (Boone, 2008 ). Since the Boone indicator is based on the negative relationship between profit and cost, a negative coefficient value of β (β < 0) is expected. A higher negative value of β indicates the presence of strong competition in the microfinance market, whereas a positive value of β shows the existence of collusion (Van Leuvensteijn et al., 2011 ).
However, obtaining the value of the Boone coefficient as specified above requires the marginal cost of MFIs and on top of that marginal cost is not measured directly. One output and three inputs are used to estimate parameters that are used to obtain the marginal cost of MFIs (Hermes et al. 2011 ). MFIs’ output proxied by gross loan portfolio. Three input costs (the cost of labor, cost of capital, and cost of fund) are used as inputs variables. The ratio of personnel expense to total assets, the ratio of financial expenses to total assets, and the ratio of administrative expenses to total assets are used as a proxy to measure the cost of labor, cost of fund, and cost of capital respectively.
Moreover, institutions level variables are added to control for the firm-specific situation. MFIs’ age (years since establishment), size (measured as the log of the total asset), ownership status (the possession of MFIs as None Bank Financial Institution, NBFI), and risk level (equity to total asset) are considered as control variables.
Model specification
FP it is the financial performance of MFI i at time t, SP it is the social performance of MFI i at time t, B jt is a degree of competition as measured by Boone indicator and M (SP it ∗ B jt ) is moderating variable obtains by multiplying mean-centered value of SP it and B jt . In both models, MFI_age, MFI_size ownership status, and MFI risk are control variables.
Estimation methods
To test the relationship between social and financial performance, Fixed Effect regression is employed. The motivation to employ Fixed Effect Model is to control for time-invariant characteristics that may bias the endogenous and exogenous variables (Baltagi, 1995 ). Additionally, the Hausman Test has applied to verify whether the error term is correlated with the predictor variables, and the result shows that the P -Value is significant, the P-Value of the Hausman test is < 0.05. Thus, the null hypothesis that the error term is not correlated with predictors is not rejected. In such a case, the Fixed Effect Model is appropriate (Greene, 2008 ).
The translog cost function (Eq. 3 ) was estimated using a stochastic frontier -the time-variant inefficient model has employed. This approach has been widely used for efficiency analysis in banking literature and recently also in microfinance literature. Footnote 4 The time-variant inefficient model states that time and entity-specific variables significantly influence the technical inefficiencies (Battese & Coelli, 1992 ). Specifically, competition is subjected to technological change. Thus, the time-variant inefficient model is important to track the effect of a time trend.
The development of competition over time (Eq. 2 ) is estimated by using Two steps Generalized Method of Moments (GMM). The motivation for applying GMM is to control the endogeneity problems that emanate from the simultaneous estimation of cost and performance (Schaeck & Čihák, 2008 ; Van Leuvensteijn et al., 2011 ). Regressing the profit variable (ROA) on the cost variable (MC) brings the endogeneity problem. It means that the change in profit also leads to a change in cost. The joint determination of these endogenous variables makes the error term to be correlated with exogenous.
In the estimation of GMM, one lag of marginal cost is used as instrumental variables. The expected values of the Boone Indicator are negative (β < 0), whereby high competition in the microfinance market is observed. The positive value of β (β > 0) indicates the existence of collusion in the market. The higher negative value of β represents the strong competition in the market. Sargan- Hansen test is also used to identify the validity of the instruments.
Data descriptions and sources
The sample consists of Indian MFIs. For this research, MFIs’ Data and India’s GNI per capital will be collected from the Microfinance Information Exchange (MIX), and World Bank development indicators respectively. MIX Market is the most widely used source of data for microfinance studies. The study is based on 10 years of penal data cover a period of 2005–2014.
Table 2 shows the general description of MFIs in the data set of this study. The analysis is based on unbalanced panel data where observation per MFI ranges from 1 year to 10 years. MFIs are included in the sample based on the availability and quality of their data. The data set uses in the study contains 183 MFIs, 84 NGOs, 83 NBMFIs, and 16 Rural Bank and Cooperative. Among 183 MFIs in the data set, 33 MFIs are young, less than 5 years operation, and 150 MFIs are mature more than 5 years operation.
Table 3 presents the summary statistics of both dependent and predictor variables used in the econometric analysis. In the statistics table, mean, standard deviation, minimum and maximum values of both dependent and explanatory variables are shown. In addition to the variables shown in Table 3 , Control variables, age dummy, and MFI ownership status dummy thoroughly included in the analysis but aren’t presented in the table.
Return on Asset and Operational Self-sufficiency (OSS) are financial performance variables. Log of Number of Active Borrower (lnNAB) and average loan portfolio to GNI (Depth) is social performance variables. The log of Total cost (TC) is used as a dependent variable in the translog cost function that applied to find marginal cost estimators. The three input prices, Financial Expense to Liability (FEL), Administrative Expense to Asset (AEA) and Personnel Expense to Asset (PEA), and output (GLP) are exogenous variables employed in the translog cost function. Similarly, the Log of Return on Asset (ROA) uses as a dependent variable in the Boone profit function to estimate the competition coefficient of the Indian microfinance market.

Analysis of results
This section presents the discussion of the estimation results of the study and the test results of the hypotheses in the conceptual framework. First, estimations on the association between social and financial performances are presented, and then competition and its moderation impacts are followed (Fig. 2 ).

Conceptual Framework of the Study with Empirical Results
Social and financial performance
Table 4 shows the regression results of the effect of social performance (SP) on financial performance (FP).
In model 1, operational self-sufficiency is regressed on social performance variables (depth and breadth of outreach) and the result shows P-Value is significant. This implies that depth and breadth of outreach have a statistically positive Footnote 5 significant relationship with operational self-sufficiency. Similarly, in model2, ROA has a positive significant relationship with depth and breadth of outreach. Thus, when outreach increases, sustainability and profitability also increase. The results confirm the hypothesis that MFIs’ social performance has a positive effect on their financial performance. Thus, this rejects the null hypothesis that there is no relationship between MFIs’ social and financial performance. These lead to support hypothesis 1 (H1) that MFIs’ social performance has a positive significant effect on financial performance. The results of this hypothesis are also in line and consistent with the study of Adhikary and Papachristou ( 2014 ), Montgomery and Weiss ( 2011 ) and Quayes ( 2012 ). They found a similar result that social outreach and financial performance (profitability and sustainability) have a positive complementary relationship. It is also in line with stakeholder theory that meeting customers’ interest is positively related to the financial performance of firms.
To check the form of relationship, one lag and one led variables are used from both depth and breadth variables. The result shows (see Appendix ) OSS has both lead and lag form of relationship with the breadth of outreach. This lag result implies that the previous year’s breadth of outreach has a positive influence on MFIs’ operational self-sufficiency of this year. Increasing the number of active borrowers in the current year will have a positive contribution to the next year’s sustainability of MFIs. Thus, participating in social development activities has a positive contribution to the MFIs’ future financial performance. Similarly, Breadth of this year has also a significant relationship with the previous year’s MFIs’ sustainability. It means the accumulation of financial resource matter to the maximizing breadth of outreach.
But, the form of relationship between OSS and depth of outreach is neither lags nor led rather cotemporal. The depth of outreach has a cotemporal relationship with OSS. On the other hand, the lag of breadth (log of the active number of borrowers) and depth of outreach are not significant with ROA.
Estimation of marginal cost parameters: translog cost function
Table 5 shows the estimation results of time-variant inefficient models, translog cost function. Most of the explanatory variables included in the model are significant with the total cost, hence partly depicts the robustness of the model. The time decay coefficient ( η ) of the model is different from 0 exposes that time and random effects are significant.
The effect of technological development that captured by year dummies Footnote 6 is also significant. Additionally, as shown in the table, the sum of input prices’ coefficient equals one proves that the linear homogeneity restriction has imposed on input prices is satisfied.
The focus of translog cost function analysis isn’t to examine the cost efficiency of MFIs, rather to finds parameters to be used for marginal cost estimations. Thus, those parameters required for calculating the marginal cost of MFI i at year t are taken from the Table 5 above and used for generating marginal cost value of MFIs at each year by substituting in the marginal cost equation, Eq. 4 .
Estimation of competition over the years
Table 6 shows the estimation of Eq. 2 using Two steps Generalized Method of Moments (GMM). In the estimation, the log of Return on Asset (ROA) is a dependent variable. Year dummies are added to capture the evolution of competition over the years.
The result of Table 6 is also shown graphically in Fig. 3 that represents the evolution of competition over the years, 2005–2014. As expected the values of the Boone coefficient are negative except for the year 2012. Thus, strong competition among Indian MFIs has been undertaken from the year 2005–2014. The positive Boone coefficient observed in the year 2012 is may be due to the presence of market collusion or MFIs were focusing on enhancing demand by increasing their cost expenditures and competition by quality (Dick, 2007 ).

Evolution of competition: Boone Indicator (BI)- (2005–2014)
The results suggest that in the period covered in this study, 2005–2012, the Indian microfinance market was very competitive. As represented in Fig. 3 , the evaluation of competition from 2005 to 2014 is somehow dynamic. In the years 2005 to 2008, the microfinance market is highly competitive whereby the competition increased at an increasing rate and then after, from 2009 to 2012, although it is competitive, it experiences a decreasing trend, but increases again after the year 2012.
Moderating effects of competition
Table 7 shows the estimation results of the competition’s moderating effect on the relationship between social and financial performance. Operational Self-Sufficiency (OSS) is a dependent variable that regressed on DEPTH, BREADTH, competition (BI), moderation term, and other control variables. The interaction term Footnote 7 is a moderating variable created by multiplying competition (BI) and DEPTH-Model 1, (M1), Footnote 8 and competition (BI) and BREADTH -model 2, (M2). Footnote 9
The moderation test focuses on whether the causal relationship between social and financial performance changes due to competition. Model one represents the moderating effect of competition on the relationship between operational self-sufficiency and depth of outreach, M1. Model 2 estimates the moderating effect of competition on the relationship between operational self-sufficiency and breadth of outreach, M2.
In model 1 the result shows that the moderating variable, M1, is significant at P -value < 0.05. Thus, moderation has occurred (Baron & Kenny, 1986 ). The study hypothesized that competition has a positive or negative moderating effect on the relationship between social and financial performance, H2. The results evidence the hypothesis that competition has a positive moderating effect on the relationship between MFIs’ social and financial performance. The results in Table 7 show the relationship between M1 (competition in model one) and OSS is significant at P -value < 0.05. Hence, hypothesis 2 (H2) is accepted. This leads to rejecting the null hypothesis that MFIs market competition doesn’t moderate the relationship between MFIs’ social and financial performance. Thus, the relationship between depths of outreach and operational self-sufficiency (OSS) is conditional upon competition. The positive β coefficient implies that competition influences the relationship between the depth of outreach and operational self-sufficiency positively. It implies that in a competitive market, the more MFI deepen their depth of outreach, the higher contribution it has to their operational self-sufficiency. As compared with the regression result found in Table 4 , the moderation isn’t partial moderation rather complete. This is because of the strength and magnitude of the relationship between depth and OSS change by competition.
Additionally, In model 2 of Table 7 , the moderating variable (M2) is not significant, so, moderation hasn’t occurred. This Implies that Competition doesn’t moderate the relationship between the breadth of outreach and operational self-sufficiency. Similarly, Table 8 shows that moderation hasn’t occurred between ROA and any of the social performance variables. Consequently, no moderation occurred
The results are partly consistent with competition-stability theory whereby in a competitive market firm becomes both financially sustainable and socially responsible. In support of this theory, the result reveals that competition strongly and positively moderates the relationship between the depth of outreach and financial performance.
Conclusions
This paper investigates the moderating effect of competition on the relationship between social and financial performances of MFIs. To examine the moderating effect of competition, first, the relationship between social and financial performance was tested. The main finding of the study indicates that social and financial performances have a positive significant relationship. When MFIs enhance their social performance by reaching out to the poor people, it boosts their profitability and sustainability.
Besides, the finding also shows that OSS and breadth of outreach have a positive significant led and lag form of relationship. Thus, MFIs’ previous year breadth of outreach affects this year’s financial performance. Similarly, MFIs’ previous year’s profitability also positively related to the following year’s breadth of outreach. But the relationship between operational self-sufficiency and depth of outreach is neither lag nor led rather cotemporal.
Moreover, competition measured by the Boone indicator reveals that during the 2005–2014 periods, the Indian microfinance market was very competitive. Surprisingly, the findings suggest that competition positively moderates the relationship between the depth of outreach and operational self-sufficiency. It appears that the association between MFIs’ depth of outreach and operational self-sufficiency is conditional upon competition. Therefore, in a competitive market, the more MFIs deepen their depth of outreach, the higher the contribution it has to their operational self-sufficiency. Competition spurring MFIs to reach out to the very poor segment of the population and helps them to be sustainable.
Furthermore, the study further supports the idea that competition doesn’t make MFIs to drift from its mission of serving poor people.
Therefore, the estimated results might allow this researcher to provide the following recommendations: first, to deepen financial outreach to the poor people, countries need to initiate and encouraging competition in their microfinance market. Along with this, policy regulators also need to design a policy framework that creates a sound competitive microfinance market. Second, to ensure a positive effect of competition, countries need to establish the institutional system that supervises and regulates the competition undergoing in the microfinance sector. Third, MFIs may consider social objective as a competitive advantage to be financial sustainability in the log-run.
In general, this paper finds robust results that competition moderates the link between social and financial performances. Therefore, this study may pave the way for upcoming empirical studies in microfinance on the moderating effect of competition on MFIs’ performance.
Practical implications for MFIs
The results bring some implications that might be useful to academics and policymakers as well as practitioners in the field. First, the positive relationship between social and financial performance suggests that although being a socially responsible institution has a financial cost, in the long-run, it positively contributes to financial performance through retain customers and increases sales volume. Second, a competitive financial system spurring MFIs to reach out to the unbanked segment of the population. Hence, competition doesn’t make MFIs to drift from their mission. It indicates that competition helps borrowers to have financial accesses and MFIs to be financially sustainable by widening the base and applying the innovative lending methodology. Third, the results show that providing financial services to the poor at an affordable price is the fundamental social responsibility that implant accountability and transparency into the microfinance sector. Last but not least, the social mission is an integral part of the microfinance sector that helps them to be financially self-sufficient.
Availability of data and materials
The data that support the findings of this study are available from the corresponding author upon reasonable request.
Double bottom line objective is refers to MFIs’ social outreach and financial sustainability (Morduch, 1999 ).
This has already applied in microfinance as output measures (see for example, Assefa et al., 2013 ; Hermes et al. ( 2011 )
All three ratios have already applied in microfinance (see Kar, 2016 ).
In microfinance see for example (Kar, 2016 ) and Hermes et al. ( 2011 ).
β coefficients of depth and breadth of outreach are positive.
Year dummies are included in the model but not reported and model test is enclosed in the Appendix .
The moderator variable is formed after mean centering of variables (B, DEPTH and BREADTH) to control multicollinearity problem that arises between the predictors and interaction term.
To capture the moderation between depth of outreach and financial performance.
To capture the moderation between breadth of outreach and financial performance.
Ackoff, R. (1970). A concept of corporate planning. Long Range Planning , 3 (1), 2–8.
Article Google Scholar
Adhikary, S., & Papachristou, G. (2014). Is there a trade-off between financial performance and outreach in South Asian microfinance institutions? The Journal of Developing Areas , 48 (4), 381–402.
Amir, R. (2003). Market structure, scale economies and industry performance. In cale economies and industry performance (September 1, 2003) .
Google Scholar
Armendáriz, B., & Szafarz, A. (2009). Microfinance mission drift . Brussels: Research Institute in Management sciences.
Assefa, E., Hermes, N., & Meesters, A. (2013). Competition and the performance of microfinance institutions. Applied Financial Economics , 23 (9), 767–782.
Baltagi, B. H. (1995). Econometric analysis of panel data , (vol. 2). New York: Wiley.
Barnett, M. L., & Salomon, R. M. (2012). Does it pay to be really good? Addressing the shape of the relationship between social and financial performance. Strategic Management Journal , 33 (11), 1304–1320.
Baron, R. M., & Kenny, D. A. (1986). The moderator–mediator variable distinction in social psychological research: Conceptual, strategic, and statistical considerations. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology , 51 (6), 1173.
Bassem, B. S. (2012). Social and financial performance of microfinance institutions: Is there a trade-off? Journal of Economics and International Finance , 4 (4), 92.
Bateman, M. (2010). Why microfinance doesn't work? The destructive rise of local neoliberalism . London: New York, Zed.
Battese, G. E., & Coelli, T. J. (1992). Frontier production functions, technical efficiency and panel data: with application to paddy farmers in India. Journal of productivity analysis , 3 (1-2), 153–169.
Beck, T. (2008). Bank competition and financial stability: Friends or foes? In World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series, vol .
Bédécarrats, F., Baur, S., & Lapenu, C. (2012). Combining social and financial performance: A paradox? Enterprise Development and Microfinance , 23 (3), 241–258.
Beisland, L. A., D’Espallier, B., & Mersland, R. (2019). The commercialization of the microfinance industry: Is there a ‘personal mission drift’among credit officers? Journal of Business Ethics , 158 (1), 119–134.
Boone, J. (2008). A new way to measure competition. The Economic Journal , 118 (531), 1245–1261.
Boyd, J. H., & De Nicolo, G. (2005). The theory of bank risk taking and competition revisited. The Journal of Finance , 60 (3), 1329–1343.
Burgess, R., & Pande, R. (2003). Do rural banks matter. In Evidence from the Indian social banking experiment. Evidence from the Indian social banking experiment (August 2003) .
Carletti, E., & Hartmann, P. (2002). Competition and stability: What’s special about banking?
Coccorese, P. (2009). Market power in local banking monopolies. Journal of Banking & Finance , 33 (7), 1196–1210.
Conning, J. (1999). Outreach, sustainability and leverage in monitored and peer-monitored lending. Journal of Development Economics , 60 (1), 51–77.
Cornell, B., & Shapiro, A. C. (1987). Corporate stakeholders and corporate finance. Financial Management , 16 (1), 5–14.
Cull, R., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Morduch, J. (2008). Microfinance meets the market. In World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series .
Cull, R., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Morduch, J. (2009). Microfinance meets the market. Journal of Economic Perspectives , 23 (1), 1–30.
Cull, R., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Morduch, J. (2011). Does regulatory supervision curtail microfinance profitability and outreach? World Development , 39 (6), 949–965.
D’Espallier, B., Goedecke, J., Hudon, M., & Mersland, R. (2017). From NGOs to banks: Does institutional transformation alter the business model of microfinance institutions? World Development , 89 , 19–33.
Datta, R. (2003). From development to empowerment: the self employed women’s Association in India. International Journal of Politics, Culture and Society , 16 (3), 351–368.
Delis, M., Iosifidi, M., & Tsionas, E. G. (2014). On the estimation of marginal cost. Operations Research , 62 (3), 543–556.
Dick, A. A. (2007). Market size, service quality, and competition in banking. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking , 39 (1), 49–81.
Etzensperger, C. (2013). Microfinance market outlook 2014: No ‘sudden stop’: Demand for microfinance soars . Zurich: ResponsAbility Investment AG.
Fombrun, C. J., Gardberg, N. A., & Barnett, M. L. (2000). Opportunity platforms and safety nets: Corporate citizenship and reputational risk. Business and Society Review , 105 (1), 85–106.
Freeman, R. E. (2010). Strategic management: A stakeholder approach . Cambridge: University Press.
Book Google Scholar
Friedman, M. (1970). A Friedman doctrine: The social responsibility of business is to increase its profits. The New York Times Magazine , 13 (1970), 32–33.
Ghate, P. (2007). Indian Microfinance: The challenges of rapid growth . SAGE Publications India.
Gonzalez, A. (2010). Microfinance Synergies and Trade-offs: Social versus Financial Performance Outcomes in 2008. MIX Data Brief No. 7 . Washington, D.C.: MIX August.
Greene, W. H. (2008). The econometric approach to efficiency analysis. In The measurement of productive efficiency and productivity growth, 92–250.
Greening, D. W., & Turban, D. B. (1996). Corporate Social Performance and Organizational Attractiveness to Prospective Employees. In Proceedings of the International Association for Business and Society , (vol. 7, pp. 489–500).
Guha, B., & Chowdhury, P. R. (2014). Borrower targeting under microfinance competition with motivated microfinance institutions and strategic complementarity. The Developing Economies , 52 (3), 211–240.
Guha, M. (2013). Are microfinance services relevant for micro-entrepreneurial growth: a case based discussion from Indian microfinance models. In Paper accepted for presentation at 4th international conference on Institutional and Technological Environment for Microfinance (ITEM4), Paris .
Guha, S. (2007). Impact of competition on microfinance beneficiaries: Evidence from India .
Gutierrez-Nieto, B., Serrano-Cinca, C., & Molinero, C. M. (2007). Microfinance institutions and efficiency. Omega , 35 (2), 131–142.
Gutiérrez-Nieto, B., Serrano-Cinca, C., & Molinero, C. M. (2009). Social efficiency in microfinance institutions. Journal of the Operational Research Society , 104–119.
Helms, B., & Reille, X. (2004). Interest rate ceilings and microfinance: The story so far (No. 33479, pp. 1-20) . The World Bank.
Hermes, N., Lensink, R., & Meesters, A. (2011). Outreach and efficiency of microfinance institutions. World Development , 39 (6), 938–948.
Hudon, M. (2011). Ethics in microfinance. In B. Armendariz, & M. Labie (Eds.), The handbook of microfinance , (pp. 123–138). London-Singapore: Scientific Work.
Chapter Google Scholar
Kanwal, M., Khanam, F., Nasreen, S., & Hameed, S. (2013). Impact of corporate social responsibility on the firm's financial performance. Journal of Business and Management , 14 (5), 67–74.
Kar, A. K. (2016). Measuring competition in microfinance markets: A new approach. International Review of Applied Economics , 30 (4), 423–440.
Khanam, D., Parvin, S. S., Mohiuddin, M., Hoque, A., & Su, Z. (2018). Financial sustainability of non-governmental microfinance institutions (MFIs): A cost-efficiency analysis of BRAC, ASA, and PROSHIKA from Bangladesh. Review of Economics & Finance , 12 (2), 43–56.
Klein, J., & Dawar, N. (2004). Corporate social responsibility and consumers’ attributions and brand evaluations in a product–harm crisis. International Journal of Research in Marketing , 21 (3), 203–217.
Lapenu, C. (2007). What microfinance for agriculture in developing countries. In Document prepared by the French Microfinance Network Rural Finance Commission .
Lau, L. J. (1982). On identifying the degree of competitiveness from industry price and output data. Economics Letters , 10 (1), 93–99.
Lebovics, M., Hermes, N., & Hudon, M. (2016). Are financial and social efficiency mutually exclusive? A case study of Vietnamese microfinance institutions. Annals of Public and cooperative Economics , 87 (1), 55–77.
Ledgerwood, J. (1999). Sustainable banking with the poor microfinance handbook .
Littlefield, E. L., & Kneiding, C. (2009). The global financial crisis and its impact on microfinance (No. 47954, pp. 1-8). Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Mader, P. (2013). Rise and Fall of Microfinance in India: The Andhra Pradesh Crisis in Perspective. Strategic Change , 22 (1-2), 47–66.
Maes, J. P., & Reed, L. R. (2012). State of the microcredit summit campaign report 2012 . Washington, DC: Microcredit Summit Campaign.
Maîtrot, M. (2019). Understanding social performance: A ‘practice drift’at the frontline of microfinance institutions in Bangladesh. Development and Change , 50 (3), 623–654.
McIntosh, C., Janvry, A., & Sadoulet, E. (2005). How rising competition among microfinance institutions affects incumbent lenders*. The Economic Journal , 115 (506), 987–1004.
McIntosh, C., & Wydick, B. (2005). Competition and microfinance. Journal of Development Economics , 78 (2), 271–298.
Mersland, R. (2011). The governance of non-profit micro finance institutions: Lessons from history. Journal of Management & Governance , 15 (3), 327–348.
Mersland, R., & Strøm, R. Ø. (2009). Performance and governance in microfinance institutions. Journal of Banking & Finance , 33 (4), 662–669.
Mersland, R., & Strøm, R. Ø. (2010). Microfinance mission drift? World Development , 38 (1), 28–36.
Montgomery, H., & Weiss, J. (2011). Can commercially-oriented microfinance help meet the millennium development goals? Evidence from Pakistan. World Development , 39 (1), 87–109.
Morduch, J. (1999). The microfinance promise. Journal of Economic Literature , 37 (4), 1569–1614.
Morduch, J. (2000). The microfinance schism. World Development , 28 (4), 617–629.
Motta, M. (2004). Competition policy: Theory and practice . Cambridge: University Press.
Navajas, S., Conning, J., & Gonzalez-Vega, C. (2003). Lending technologies, competition and consolidation in the market for microfinance in Bolivia. Journal of International Development , 15 (6), 747–770.
Navajas, S., Schreiner, M., Meyer, R. L., Gonzalez-Vega, C., & Rodriguez-Meza, J. (2000). Microcredit and the poorest of the poor: Theory and evidence from Bolivia. World Development , 28 (2), 333–346.
Nawaz, A., & Iqbal, S. (2015). Financial performance and corporate governance in microfinance: Who drives who? An evidence from Asia .
Ngo, T. V. (2015). Microfinance complementarity and trade-off between financial performance and social impact. International Journal of Economics and Finance , 7 (11), 128.
Olsen, T. D. (2010). New actors in microfinance lending: The role of regulation and competition in Latin America. Perspectives on Global Development and Technology , 9 (3), 500–519.
Orlitzky, M., & Benjamin, J. D. (2001). Corporate social performance and firm risk: A meta-analytic review. Business & Society , 40 (4), 369–396.
Panzar, J. C., & Rosse, J. N. (1987). Testing for “monopoly” equilibrium. The Journal of Industrial Economics , 35 (4), 443–456.
Porteous, D. (2006). Competition and interest rates in microfinance. (no. 33) . Washington DC: CGAP Focus Note.
Preston, L. E., & O'bannon, D. P. (1997). The corporate social-financial performance relationship. Business and Society , 36 (4), 419.
Quayes, S. (2012). Depth of outreach and financial sustainability of microfinance institutions. Applied Economics , 44 (26), 3421–3433.
Ribstein, L. E. (2005). Accountability and responsibility in corporate governance. Notre Dame L.Rev. , 81 , 1431.
Robinson, M. S. (2001). The microfinance revolution: Sustainable finance for the poor . Washington, DC.: The World Bank.
Rosenberg, R., Gonzalez, A., & Narain, S. (2009). Are microcredit interest rates excessive? CGAP brief .
Ruf, B. M., Muralidhar, K., Brown, R. M., Janney, J. J., & Paul, K. (2001). An empirical investigation of the relationship between change in corporate social performance and financial performance: A stakeholder theory perspective. Journal of Business Ethics , 32 (2), 143–156.
Schaeck, K., & Čihák, M. (2008). How does competition affect efficiency and soundness in banking? New empirical evidence .
Schicks, J., & Rosenberg, R. (2011). Too much microcredit?: A survey of issues and evidence on over-indebtedness among micro-borrowers. In CGAP occasional paper .
Schreiner, M. (2002). Aspects of outreach: A framework for discussion of the social benefits of microfinance. Journal of International Development , 14 (5), 591–603.
Servet, J. (2011). Corporate responsibility versus social performance and financial inclusion. In The handbook of microfinance , (pp. 301–322). Singapore: World Scientific.
Shah, M., Rao, R., & Shankar, P. V. (2007). Rural credit in 20th century India: Overview of history and perspectives. Economic and Political Weekly , 42 (15), 1351–1364.
Sharma, A. (2006). Microfinance: Hope for the Poor , (vol. 100, p. 31). DELHI: YOJANA.
Simpson, W. G., & Kohers, T. (2002). The link between corporate social and financial performance: Evidence from the banking industry. Journal of Business Ethics , 35 (2), 97–109.
Taylor, M. (2011). ‘Freedom from poverty is not for free’: Rural development and the microfinance crisis in Andhra Pradesh, India. Journal of Agrarian Change , 11 (4), 484–504.
Van Leuvensteijn, M., Bikker, J. A., van Rixtel, A. A., & Sørensen, C. K. (2011). A new approach to measuring competition in the loan markets of the euro area. Applied Economics , 43 (23), 3155–3167.
Vance, S. C. (1975). Are socially responsible corporations good investment risks. Management Review , 64 (8), 19–24.
Vanroose, A., & D’Espallier, B. (2013). Do microfinance institutions accomplish their mission? Evidence from the relationship between traditional financial sector development and microfinance institutions’ outreach and performance. Applied Economics , 45 (15), 1965–1982.
Villas-Boas, J. M., & Schmidt-Mohr, U. (1999). Oligopoly with asymmetric information: Differentiation in credit markets. The Rand Journal of Economics , 30 (3), 375–396.
Vogelgesang, U. (2003). Microfinance in times of crisis: The effects of competition, rising indebtedness, and economic crisis on repayment behavior. World Development , 31 (12), 2085–2114.
Wichterich, C. (2012). The Other Financial Crisis: Growth and crash of the microfinance sector in India. Development , 55 (3), 406–412.
Woller, G. (2002). The promise and peril of microfinance commercialization. Small Enterprise Development , 13 (4), 12–21.
Download references
Acknowledgements
In presenting this review, I would like to express my gratitude to my collegues for their helpful ideas, and kind responses to my questions during the entire phases of my study.
Not applicable.
Author information
Authors and affiliations.
College of Business and Economics, Bahir Dar University, Bahir Dar, Ethiopia
Hailu Abebe Wondirad
You can also search for this author in PubMed Google Scholar
Contributions
Hailu Abebe Wondirad is a corresponding author who major wrote the manuscript. The author(s) read and approved the final manuscript.
Corresponding author
Correspondence to Hailu Abebe Wondirad .
Ethics declarations
Competing interests.
The authors declare that they have no competing interests
Additional information
Publisher’s note.
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Rights and permissions
Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ .
Reprints and Permissions
About this article
Cite this article.
Wondirad, H. Competition and microfinance institutions’ performance: evidence from India. Int J Corporate Soc Responsibility 5 , 6 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40991-020-00047-1
Download citation
Received : 09 October 2019
Accepted : 13 July 2020
Published : 24 October 2020
DOI : https://doi.org/10.1186/s40991-020-00047-1
Share this article
Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:
Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.
Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative
- Microfinance
- Boone Indicator
- Social performance
- Financial performance
Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.
To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to upgrade your browser .
Enter the email address you signed up with and we'll email you a reset link.
- We're Hiring!
- Help Center
A Study on Microfinance in India
by parveen kumar
— Microfinance is a source of fi nance to the poor segments of society. It i ncludes loans, savi ngs, credit, insurance services, money transfer and other basic financial services to the economically weaker section of society. Deli very mechanism incorporates the systems that can be used to ensure that micro finance products reach remote area and poor. It is consi dered as an effecti ve tool for eli minating poverty in Indi a. It provi des credit and other financial services of small amount to the economically disadvantaged segment of society in urban as well as rural areas. Micro finance institutions include N.G.Os, Credit Uni ons, N.B.F.Cs. Cooperati ves and banks. In India, the future of microfinance is largely depending upon the self-help groups (S.H.G.)
- Access 47 million research papers for free
- Keep up-to-date with the latest research
- Share your research and grow your audience
- We're Hiring!
- Help Center
- Find new research papers in:
- Health Sciences
- Earth Sciences
- Cognitive Science
- Mathematics
- Computer Science
- Academia ©2023
Free Related PDFs
Joysa Agrawall
In a country like India where 70 percent of its population lives in rural area and 60 percent depend on agriculture (according to the World Bank reports), micro-finance can play a vital role in providing financial services to the poor and low income individuals. Microfinance is the form of a broad range of financial services such as deposits, loans, payment services, money transfers, insurance, savings, micro-credit etc. to the poor and low income individuals. The importance of micro-finance in the developing economies like India can not be undermined, where a large size of population is living under poverty and large number of people does not have an access to formal banking facilities. The taskforce on Supportive Policy and Regulatory Framework for Microfinance constituted by NABARD defined microfinance as " the provision of thrift, saving, credit and financial services and products of very small amount to the poor's in rural, semi urban and urban areas for enabling them to raise their income level and improve their standard of living. " (Sen, 2008) Micro-finance is regarded as a useful tool for socioeconomic up-liftmen in a developing country like India. It is expected to play a significant role in poverty alleviation and development. There are two broad approaches that characterize the microfinance sector in India is Self Help Groups (SHGs)-Bank linkage programme and Microfinance Institution (MFIs). In India microfinance is dominated by Self Help Groups (SHGs)-Bank linkage programme aimed at providing a cost effective mechanism for providing financial services to the unreached poor. The present paper aims at identifying the current status and role of microfinance in the development of India.

Rachana Vishwakarma
2014, International Journal of Research in Economics and Social Sciences

Publisher ijmra.us UGC Approved
Microfinance is gathering momentum to become a significant force in India. The self helpgroup (SHG) model with bank lending to groups of (often) poor women without collateral has become an accepted part of rural finance. The paper discusses the state of SHG-based microfinance in India and the opportunity untapped because of the huge existing demand-supply gap. With traditionally loss-making rural banks shifting their portfolio away from the rural poor in the post-reform period, SHG-based microfinance, nurtured and aided by NGOs, have become an important alternative to traditional lending in terms of reaching the poor without incurring a fortune in operating and monitoring costs. The government and NABARD have recognized this and have emphasized the SHG approach and working along with NGOs in its initiatives. In spite of the impressive figures, the supply side of microfinance in India is still presently grossly inadequate to fill the gap between demand and supply but it holds the promise to act as a great opportunity for the financial sector and the economy as a whole.

Dr. Sanjeeb Kumar Dey
2015, Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development

Pawan Kumar Bhura , Ashutosh K U M A R Jha
2019, International Journal of Applied Research
Microfinance is a source of financial support for low income people such as rural poor people, low income clients, small entrepreneurs who have limited money to do business. In this system, people who have difficulty in accessing financial support, microfinance helps them to grow their business by providing financial support. They provide various financial services like loans, deposits, savings accounts, money transfers insurance etc. Micro-finance has received extensive recognition as a method for poverty alleviation in India as well as the developing economy. In India Micro-finance today could be a dynamic space with many of players offering different products and services to the poor and low income people small entrepreneurs like banks, NBFCs, Section 25 companies, different cooperatives and NGOs, MFIs all are approaching rural markets. Microfinance is specially designed for the needy people and a section of the society living in underdeveloped areas who want to stand on their own feet and Microfinance service restored to help them. Sector wise position of bank credit disbursed to SHGs during the last three years as shown by Single Factor ANOVA. This paper is an attempt to know about the role of micro-finance on poverty alleviation in India, models and major challenges faced by microfinance in India. Keywords: Micro-finance, poverty alleviation, NBFCs, NGOs, MFIs

Sibghatullah Nasir
Microfinance refers to small savings, credit and insurance services extended to socially and economically disadvantaged segments of society. It is emerging as a powerful tool for poverty alleviation in India. This working paper tries to outline the prevailing condition of the Microfinance in India in the light of its emergence till now. The prospect of Micro-Finance is dominated by SHGs (Self Help Groups) - Banks linkage Program. Its main aim is to provide a cost effective mechanism for providing financial services to the poor. Recently Union Rural Development Minister Jairam Ramesh wanted the help of SHGs for the establishment of DRDO designed bio-toilets in rural areas. This paper discovers the prevailing gap in functioning of MFIs such as practices in credit delivery, lack of product diversification, customer overlapping and duplications, consumption and individual loan demand with lack of mitigation measures, less thrust on enterprise loans, collection of savings/loans and highe...

2016, Indian Journal of Economics and Development
The main objective this paper is to understand the concept of microfinance, the operation and to identify the latest issues, problems and challenges in effective implementation of various Microfinance programmes. The study reveals that While Micro Finance Sector seems to be growing fast with no road blockages, it has also brought to fore several challenges and issues. Some of such issues are: providing varietal savings avenues to the micro finance beneficiaries, and mobilization of such savings by MFIs, creating regulatory frame work for MFIs, provision of finance to MFIs as a regular channel of finance/refinance, reduction in cost of resources/management resulting in lending rates for micro finance beneficiaries, safety and precautions for MFIs entering into new financial services like micro leasing, insurance, housing, medical services etc.

Journal ijmr.net.in(UGC Approved)
Throughout this paper, we tried to discuss the progress of microfinance programme in India. The main objective of microfinance programme is to provide financing facilities to those areas of thrust from where the generation of income and the employment may be takes place. There are certain principles and delivery models also through which the microfinance process takes place. In this regard, Self Help groups play a vital role. In this sector, many banks (public and private), NGOs, Cooperative banks have shown very keen interest. There are also many programmes/schemes through various agencies and departments are going on to promote the SHGs. In addition, it also provides the services of Micro savings, Micro insurance, Micro Leasing and the money transfer which are similar to banking services.

Govindarajan Vedanthadesikan
Microfinance stands as one of the most promising and cost effective tools which fight against global poverty. The findings from this study suggests that there is rise in the history and perspectives of rural credit in India in form of microfinance and there is need for improved governance to manage challenges for future so that socioeconomic growth is possible. The present paper discusses conceptual framework, development process, growth of SHG linked microfinance programme, types of micro finance services and developmental role of these institutions in rural India. It also focuses on the status of microfinance and provides some policy framework to meet the challenges faced by Indian microfinance. The article traces that the evolution of the microfinance revolution in India as a powerful tool for socioeconomic development in rural India.

ravi bardia

anisha koushal
One of the greatest challenges before the Indian sub-continent which accommodates more than one-third of the population is poverty. India, one of the BRIC nations with more than 1.2 billion population is seen by many developed countries as an emerging economy. India " s economic growth has failed to make a significant improvement in its poverty figures with 400 million-more than the total in the poorest African Nations-still stuck in poverty. Government of India with its concern started various poverty alleviation programs but they have failed to deliver the objectives to the level which is desired. The reasons may be many such as failure to reach the target group, loopholes in the system, developing a robust mechanism to name a few. Many countries including India experimented with subsidized credit which only led to increase in the NPAs. The microfinance has come forward to fill up the gap. But the outreach is too small as compared to the requirement and potential. However there is some progress in this regard after active role played by NABARD and formation of SHGs groups. A number of NGOs and MFIs have also delved into the business. Some of them have also started in a big way and have started making profit by issuing IPOs (Initial public offers). But certain development in recent years has brought a fresh focus on the problem of regulation in field of microfinance. The paper delineates three distinct aspects of microfinance, first growth of microfinance in India and some other countries; secondly it discusses the role played by NABARD and other National Banks in growth of SHGs and Grameen Bank. Third, it deals with the role of government in framing legislation for protection of right of micro borrowers. The study also deals with the need for a regulatory body to regulate, develop and guide the numerous MFIs and NGOs who work in the field of microcredit. The paper discusses the factors and theoretical position associated with evolution of microfinance and its role in global scenario.

anjali jain

Research Papers
In a country like India, poverty remains to be one of the biggest problem. Amongst various measures to eradicate it, microfinance, of late has provided a ray of hope. The taskforce on Supportive Policy and Regulatory Framework for Microfinance constituted by NABARD defined microfinance as " the provision of thrift, saving, credit and financial services and products of very small amount to the poor's in rural, semi urban and urban areas for enabling them to raise their income level and improve their standard of living." (Sen, 2008). Microfinance is emerging as a powerful instrument to eradicate poverty and to achieve inclusive growth. In India microfinance scene is dominated by Self Help Groups (SHGs)-Bank linkage programme aimed at providing a cost effective mechanism for providing financial services to the unreached poor. The present study aims at identifying the role of microfinance in the development of India.

2020, International Journal of Scientific & Technology Research
Micro Finance emerges as an anti-poverty program which is accepted and adopted by every continent and every country. The global nature of the Micro Finance movement is reflected in the growing number of organizations providing Micro finance to poor people. The value of Microfinance and its potential as a tool to help most of the country’s poorest people, evidenced in the substantial track recorded of accomplishment in the recent past. Microfinance programmes allow small loans to poorest people by introducing self-employment generation scheme which helps to earn revenue, make efficient for earning their livelihood independently. Microfinance programmes gives opportunities not only credit but also give services in the form of training and development. Micro Finance is the cost effective and complementary means of rural credit disbursement system, which promotes the quick and timely availability of institutional credit in an economical and effective manner and in small fund without too...

Microfinance is defined as any activity that includes the provision of financial services such as credit, savings, and insurance to low income individuals which fall just above the nationally defined poverty line, and poor individuals which fall below that poverty line, with the goal of creating social value. The creation of social value includes poverty alleviation and the broader impact of improving livelihood opportunities through the provision of capital for micro enterprise, and insurance and savings for risk mitigation and consumption smoothing. A large variety of actors provide microfinance in India, using a range of microfinance delivery methods. Since the ICICI Bank in India, various actors have endeavored to provide access to financial services to the poor in creative ways. Governments also have piloted national programs, NGOs have undertaken the activity of raising donor funds for on-lending, and some banks have partnered with public organizations or made small inroads themselves in providing such services. This has resulted in a rather broad definition of microfinance as any activity that targets poor and low-income individuals for the provision of financial services.

Indus Foundation International Journals UGC Approved
Due to unavailable and improper reach of formal financial services, the rural low income population resort to money lenders for immediate availability of credit as money lenders have been viewed as a tool which provides immediate credit for essential needs. As money lenders give credit immediately, they charge exorbitant prices. This in turn could lead to a debt trap. In this context, Microfinance has emerged as a powerful effective mechanism tool for poverty alleviation, empowerment and financial inclusion in India. The present study is explorative in nature and entirely based on secondary data and it also dwells upon the role of microfinance towards empowering people and to identify the opportunities and challenges associated with the growth of microfinance sector in realising financial inclusion in Indian perspective.

Vanya Chaturvedi
India, a country where poverty strikes at its core, an economy that is predominantly agrarian and where a sizeable percentage of the population dwells below the poverty line is in much need of financial resources for the have-nots. This is not merely due to the fact of them being poor, but, more significantly due to the fact that the financial inclusion of all classes into the economic mainstream is a must and has always been the State’s paramount goal. This has to be done in order to ensure that wealth is equitably distributed and the benefits of economic development are enjoyed fully by each and every section of the society. This study analyses the various domains of microfinance, as, it is a key ingredient in ensuring the financial inclusion of the weaker economic classes. It analyses the various models of microfinance prevalent in India and its key emphasis is to identify the key economic and legal problem areas that emerge in the regulation and flow of microfinance. The study primarily bases itself on secondary data and is an effort to analyze the roadblocks and to further suggest corrective strategies and implementation measures for the same. The model primarily focused on is the Self-Help Groups Bank Linkage Programme (hereafter referred to as SHG-BLP). It also imparts focus on the legal situation of microfinance in India, so as to analyze the inherent lacunas and recommend solutions as analyzed during the course of the study. KEYWORDS: Microfinance, financial inclusion, SHG-BLP, legal aspect, economically weaker sections

IJAR Indexing
The present paper highlights the microfinance and role of microfinance in achieving financial inclusion in Indian Economy. The concept of Micro Finance is not new in India. Traditionally people have saved with and taken small loans from individuals and groups within the context of self help to start businesses or farming ventures. Majority of poor are excluded from financial services. Microfinance is a programme to support the poor rural people to pay its debts and maintain social and economic status in the villages. Microfinance is an important tool for improving the standard of living of poor. In spite of many organizations of microfinance, microfinance is not sufficient in india.The potential of growing microfinance institution in India is very high., as it is supported by government of India to achieve greater financial inclusion and growth in the country?s priority sector. The study explores problems in microfinance sector and suggestions to make microfinance more effective in Indian economy to benefit major section of society and to achieve greater Financial Inclusion with the help of Microfinance Institutions.

Kibuule Ronald

Prof Dhiresh Kulshrestha

Sulaiman Muhammad
2012, SSRN Electronic Journal

Jahangir Bhat
Economists have long agreed that access to finance plays an essential role in the process of dipping the inequality in wealth distribution, it enhancing the household income and provide better employment opportunities. Microfinance in India is now mounting and covering wider boundaries more importantly it gets appreciations as a tool to reduce poverty. It has become a critical tool for reaching all those under privileged groups such as women, socially and economically backward classes for the purpose of empowerment and providing access to the financial services. It is a cost effective mechanism for providing financial services to the poor. This working paper tries to outline the prevailing conditions of the Microfinance in India. Further the paper the paper is highlighting the financial & promotional support by NABARD and SIDBI in the sector of microfinance. Abstract-Economists have long agreed that access to finance plays an essential role in the process of dipping the inequality in wealth distribution, it enhancing the household income and provide better employment opportunities. Microfinance in India is now mounting and covering wider boundaries more importantly it gets appreciations as a tool to reduce poverty. It has become a critical tool for reaching all those under privileged groups such as women, socially and economically backward classes for the purpose of empowerment and providing access to the financial services. It is a cost effective mechanism for providing financial services to the poor. This working paper tries to outline the prevailing conditions of the Microfinance in India. Further the paper the paper is highlighting the financial & promotional support by NABARD and SIDBI in the sector of microfinance.

Manish Didwania
Increasing access of financial services to deprived section of society is the main motto of Microfinance. In this regard development of microenterprises plays a crucial role for sustainable economic development. The two words microfinance and micro credit can be used interchangeably which means provision of financial services to those living in poverty and excluded from the financial system. These people do not have income nor own a property and therefore, are unable to provide Bank guarantees, as a result of which they are generally forgotten by financial Institutions and Banks. Microfinance has gained a lot of importance and momentum in the last decade. Today microfinance become one of the most debated and documented but still much confused buzzwords in banking and policy making fields. In present study an attempt has been made to reveal the facts pertains to structure of MFIs in India and Bangladesh. Subsequent discussion has been divided in to four sections. Section I comprises ...

Stuart Rutherford
Background paper prepared for the World Bank
Poor households face many constraints in trying to save, invest, and protect their livelihoods. They take financial intermediation seriously and devote considerable effort to finding workable solutions. Most of the solutions ...

Dr. Sakshi Varshney

Parijat Dhar
Microfinance is an important institution and mechanism of credit delivery, particularly for the poor and deprived. A number of studies have been taken up in India and other developing countries which highlight the success of various microfinance programmes to alleviate poverty in rural areas, promoting holistic development of individuals, communities and developing small enterprises to promote entrepreneurship development particularly for the womenfolk. The importance of the microfinance programmes and the success of the institutions offering microfinance services in various developing countries come to the fore due to the persistent failure and non-responsiveness of the formal financial institutions in the sphere of rural development in general and rural credit in particular. In India there are two different models adopted for the delivery of microfinance services to the poor-Self Help Groups (SHGs) and Microfinance Institutions (MFIs). But the penetration of these two models have ...

Pritam Chatterjee
2021, International Journal of Humanities and Social Science Invention
Indian microfinance is huge industry to empower low income group and unorganised sector. Now a day microfinance is an alternative of viable business along with social development. At the same time the sector faces huge criticism and challenges from every stakeholders after the Andhra Pradesh crisis in 2010. After 2010, microfinance today is a highly regulated industry with the purpose, segment of clients, size of loans, and even price being regulated. As now it is regulated by the RBI, the political risks are also reduced. There are more than one way to provide a finance to poor people. Self Help Group (SHG) is a main component of microfinance. SHG mainly is a group culture to provide women a financial support or draw them into work force. SHG is a channel through which facility of microfinance reach to every door of marginalised sector. In this project, we want to established how microfinance helps poor peoples and how through SHG microfinance reach to every marginalised people. Our objective is to analyse impact of microfinance as a tool of Economic Development in India.In this project,we basically want to analyse performance of three types of microfinance institutions.These are-i)MFI(Microfinance Institutions) ii)SHG (Self Help Groups)and iii)JLG.(Joint Liability Groups).Datas are collected from RBI and NABARD. Our special focus is on SHG as SHG plays an important role in case of microfinance.In case of SHG,we are focusing on yearwise performance of SHG and SHG under NRLM (National Rural Livelihood Mission).Lastly,we calculate Average number of SHG Per state.In each cases,our time period is from 2010-11 to 2017-18,The details performance of these three types of institutions analysed graphically.We also run a correlation coefficient between performance of SHG and SHG under NRLM to judge whether NRLM is a successful mission or not.

IAEME Publication
2022, IAEME PUBLICATION
In a country like India where 70 percent of its population lives in rural area and 60 percent depend on agriculture (according to the World Bank reports), micro-finance can play a vital role in providing financial services to the poor and low income individuals. Micro-finance is regarded as a useful tool for socio-economic upliftment in a developing country like India. It is expected to play a significant role in poverty alleviation and development. The emphasis of present paper is to study the performance and role of microfinance institutions in the development of India. Indian economy is portrayed by low rate of development, predominance of rural population, overwhelming dependency on horticulture, unfavorable land mass proportion, exceptionally skewed income distribution and wealth beside, high frequency of destitution and joblessness. The last two variables poverty and joblessness posture real difficulties to the development and success of the nation. To conquer this issue, some recently created parts likemicro finance are assuming an essential part. Microfinance has been viewed as a capable tool to battle poverty through the arrangement of essential financial services including reserve funds, protection, credit and transfer of funds. Microfinance has changed from being an experiment alternative option to formal or casual sources of credit to be a model for lending projects to the poor of developing nations. Microfinance has permitted giving credit to poor people who were not given the credit by the financial institutions reason for lacking of collateral assets. The target of microfinance establishments is to serve needy individuals and empower them to get to credit and fight poverty. The study revealed that the number of MFIs availing loans from banks during the year 2019-20 and 2020-21 increased from 9.8 per cent to 257.6 per cent. The total loans to MFIs by banks decreased during 2016-17 by 7.2 per cent over the previous year. The loan outstanding against MFIs increased all the subsequent years. It increased by 13.7 per cent and 14.3 per cent in 2019-20 and 2020-21. It is further found that the business models of MFIs in India are becoming urban centric as is indicated by the fact that the share of rural client’s base of different states/UTs in 2021 with 2016 has declined, except Assam, Arunachal Pradesh, Nagaland, Jammu & Kashmir and Andaman. The highest increase was in Andaman (267%) followed by Jammu & Kashmir (17 %), The proportion of income generation loan remained same during year 2020 and it increased up to94 per cent in the year 2021. The indicators relating to overall financial structure such as Return on assets and Return on equity, capital adequacy ratio have increased over this period and found sharp decline in total assets of MFI’s.

IOSR Journals publish within 3 days
Microfinance is defined as any activity that includes the provision of financial services such as credit, savings, and insurance to low income individuals which fall just above the nationally defined poverty line, and poor individuals which fall below that poverty line, with the goal of creating social value. The creation of social value includes poverty alleviation and the broader impact of improving livelihood opportunities through the provision of capital for micro enterprise, and insurance and savings for risk mitigation and consumption smoothing. This research paper seeks to identify the risks and challenges facing the microfinance industry as seen by practitioners, investors, regulators and observers of the microfinance industry and others. Microfinance has undergone plenty of changes in the last decade; many trends have emerged and the service scope of many financial services has changed too (for instance, mobile banking has evolved over the last several years). Overall, the survey highlighted significant concerns about the future of microfinance and the need for critical issues to be addressed in order to ensure the long-term survival of the industry. So this survey explores the main risks and challenges facing by the microfinance industry.

Sulagna Das , Sulagna Das

This research paper involves study of the past literatures about the microfinance sector, related online research papers and journals. The annual reports and the sector reports published by regulatory bodies, MFI associations and major microfinance players facilitated the study, especially in understanding the size, growth and past trends. Interactions with some of the experts helped in understanding and analyzing the emerging concerns in the microfinance sector and also to look for some possible solutions. The study covers the micro financing in priority states of India for the period 2010 to 2013, Potential Rural households to be covered, Rural households covered* (SHG: Savings linked) Districts with low coverage of SHGs, Average savings / SHG (Rs), Average credit disbursed / SHG (Rs), Loans issued No. of SHGs (lakh), Loans issued (Rs crore), Loans outstanding (Rs crore), Gross NPA (Rs crore), SGSY (Rs crore), SHG (non-SGSY) (Rs crore) and No. of WSHG districts. Findings of study show that various micro financing activities and institutions have grown intensively in Southern India and many poor people mostly woman are participating actively in micro financing activities. Further the impact of microfinance is also analyzed on women empowerment and it turns out to be positive. Overall, the finance schemes are spreading all over India over the last few years.

Gunjan Princess

Dr. Ajit Bansal
Year 2005 was called international year of microcredit by United Nations. Since, micro finance has proven to be an effective tool for poverty reduction. Microfinance is the provision of financial services to low-income clients, including consumers and the self-employed, who traditionally lack access to banking and related services. More broadly, it is a movement whose object is “a world in which as many poor and near-poor households as possible have permanent access to an appropriate range of high quality financial services, including not just credit but also savings, insurance, and fund transfers.” Those who promote microfinance generally believe that such access will help poor people out of poverty. The dynamic growth of the microfinance industry has been promoted not only by market forces but also by conscious actions of national governments, Non-Governmental Organizations (NGOs) and the donors who view microfinance as an effective tool for eradicating poverty. The powerful push ...

Mannar Badur
2021, Allied Business Academies
One can still have literature sources in works such as narratives, observations, assignments, communication, article, books, rhyme, dissertations, programs, and theory, along with others. This is why literature review engrosses examining the pages of any in print literature like books, newspapers, magazines, websites, webpage, assortment, paper, brochures, and the like where you may be capable to discover some reference to the matching matter that you are researching on. This article provides a review of the recent literature on microfinance in developing countries and a critical assessment of its effectiveness. It examines the experience of India, which has one of the largest microfinance sectors in the world, and particularly the unfolding of the microfinance crisis in Andhra Pradesh. It concludes that microfinance cannot be seen as a silver bullet for development and that profit-oriented microfinance institutions are problematic. To fulfil even some of its progressive goals, it must be regulated and subsidised, and other strategies for viable financial inclusion of the poor and of small producers must be more actively pursued.

Microfinance is the provision of financial services such as credit, savings and insurance to low-income individuals with the goal of creating social value. India is one of the fastest growing economies; despite fast-paced growth, two thirds of the population lives on less than US $2 a day. This study analyses the performance of select Micro Finance Institutions (MFIs) inIndia. In a country like India 70 percent of the population lives in rural areas while the rest of the population, i.e. 30 percent resides in urban areas and 60 percent depend on agriculture (according to the World Bank reports), micro-finance can play a crucial role in providing financial services to the poor and low income people. Microfinance means arange of financial services like deposits, instalment payments, loans, money payment services, money transfers, insurance, savings, micro-credit services to the poor and low income individuals. Microfinance also refers to those financial services which include providing tiny loans, credits facilities and deposits that are provided to the people at the time of their urgent needs who operate small businesses or enterprises. Microfinance also helps to provide loans to the poor and needy people at a very low interest rate. At present, there are many societies, companies, entities, trusts, bodies and such other institutions that are engaged in providing microfinance services to the poor people for their household purposes as a complementary to the banking system. In a country like India, there is always the importance of microfinance because there are a number of people who are living under poverty and have lack of money and also they do not have any access to the facilities provided by banks. Performance of select MFIs with respect to five major indicators is taken up.These are Outreach Indicators, Financing Structure, Overall Financial Performance, Efficiency and Productivity Indicators and Portfolio Quality Indicators. The mean values for all the MFIs for the said period is taken across several parameters for the above mentioned indicators. It was found that most of the MFIs performed well prior to microfinance crisis. Though all MFIs were operationally selfsufficient, improvement with respect to ROE, ROA and reduction in cost per borrower is solicited.

shubhra rahul
In developing economies and particularly in rural areas, many activities that would be classified in the developed world as financial are non-monetized: that is, money is not used to carry them out. This is often the case when people need the services money can provide but do not have dispensable funds required for those services, forcing them to revert to other means of acquiring them. Often money is needed for the purposes; by a chunk of the population like lifecycle needs such as weddings, funerals, childbirth, education, home building, widowhood and old age, personal emergencies such as sickness, injury, unemployment, theft, harassment or disasters such as fires, floods, cyclones and man-made events like war or bulldozing of dwellings, investment opportunities: expanding a business, buying land or equipment, improving housing, securing a job (which often requires paying a large bribe). This paper is divided into two parts, perspectives and operations of Micro Finance. Perspecti...

RISHI BHARGAV DAS
The basic assumption of this paper is that rural development in India should not be seen as a package of specific needs but as a transformation of rural life and conditions of the country. In this paper, it is assumed that the term rural development means the overall development of rural areas on a sustainable basis. In this background, the paper attempts to explain the link between the microfinance services and rural development. The paper also argues that microfinance is not a magic bullet for poverty reduction and rural development in India. The paper which is conceptual in nature is totally based on secondary data.

P. Srinivasa Rao , Jaya Priyadarshini Yarikipati
Informal sector lenders remain a strong presence in rural India in terms of providing credit facilities in rural India. Farmers and rural poor borrowings from Money lenders and other informal sources of rural credit still significant this sources some extent i.e. 77 percent to 32 percent. In this situation micro finance has emerged as an alternative source of rural credit, microfinance programmes has providing all kinds of banking services, it includes loans, thrifts and insurance services. Sometimes it is working more than financial institutions. In addition to providing financial services MFIs typically provide information related to basic education, health, hygiene, child immunization, disease prevention and environment surely one cannot deny the role of microfinance in poverty reduction as it raises income and consumption of poor households. Around the world 128 million people were received microcredit. The growth of microfinance borrowers in the context of India consist of two dominated models SBLP and MFIs increases from 48.0 to 93.9 million in between 2006-2011years. Major findings of this study explore the relationship between rural credit and microfinance instead of non-institutional sources of rural credit. The impact of microfinance on burden of rural debt is declined sharply, especially moneylenders and other non-institutional contribution in terms of lending to farmers, poor and women borrowings is going to downwards. Well managed and regulated microfinance programmes (particularly rate of interest, forced recovery of microcredit loans) augmented rural sector employment, productivity of non-agriculture sector, establishment of MSMEs, empowerment of women in socioeconomic aspects, it enhances health and educational facilities. Another important impact of microfinance programmes is that reduction of income and consumption disparities, especially vulnerable sections of the society will get the benefits from collateral or guarantee free. Microfinance programmes implies that the consumption pattern, it encourages from non-productivity expenditure to productive expenditure because of timely repayments of loans.

Murlidhar Lokhande
Micro-fiancé programme has a significant has role to play in Indian economy for boosting micro entrepreneurial activities for creating productive assets coupled with employment generation. According to the planning Commission of India around 40,000 crores have been spent on poverty alleviation programmes (PAPs). However, a large section of Indian population is shell living below poverty line. Poverty has multi-dimensional effects i.e. low income, literacy, ill health, gender inequality and degradation of environment. During 1973-74 the population living below poverty (BPL) was 56.44% (31 crore). It reduced to 37.27% (32 crore) and 26.10% (26 crore) during 1993-94 and 2003-04 respectively. Poverty means denial of access to the basic necessities. i.e. food, shelter, health, education of human existence. Poverty is characterized by lower standard of living. As per a study, if poverty is measured by the international poverty line i.e. 1 $ a day, the percentage of BPL population in India comes 34.9% and if we fix poverty line 3 $ a day the percentage of BPL in India comes to 79.9% (Human Development Report, 2004). Basically, poverty is the effect of lack of income and access to credit.

Dr. Ch. Venkata Krishna Reddy
Micro-credit intervention programme has been well-recognized world over as an effective tool for poverty alleviation and for improving socio-economic conditions of rural poor. In India too, micro-credit is making a strong headway in its efforts to reduce poverty and empower the rural poor. The rural poor, with the intermediation of voluntary organizations join together for self help to secure better economic growth. This has resulted in the formation of a large number of self help groups in the country, which mobilize savings and recycle the resources generated among the members. Despite various poverty alleviation programmes initiated by Government as well as voluntary organizations, not much difference has been seen in the magnitude of poverty. Notwithstanding an impressive coverage, the formal banking sector has had a limited impact on lending to the poor. Over its entire lifetime, the formal rural banking system in India has struggled to balance the dual objectives of outreach and financial performance. Consequently, there was a need to put in place a new vehicle of financial intermediaries, which could be cost-effective for the banks and user-friendly for the poor. This way, the poor could related to banks in a better manner, and the banks, in turn, could consider banking with them as a better business proposition. The challenge, therefore, was to link a large number of economically underprivileged ones to the formal banking sector, in a sustainable and cost-effective manner. As on 31 March 2010, the Commercial Banks lead with savings accounts of 40,52,915 SHGs (58.3%) followed by RRBs having savings bank accounts of 18,20,870 SHGs (26.2%) and Cooperative Banks having savings bank accounts of 1,079,465 SHGs (15.5%). In spite of the volumes, it has been ascertained that these mandatory and dedicated, subsidized financial programmes, implemented through banking institutions, have not been effective in achieving their social and economic objectives. Several defective features in the planning and implementation of these government sponsored programmes, followed in different countries, have been responsible in greater or lesser degrees for the state of affairs. After nearly three decades of implementation, the substantial efforts and large volumes of credit extended by the banks have not been able to result in the expected benefits to the poor, mainly due to certain inherent contradictions in programme implementation. An efficient and viable credit delivery system catering to a large section of the poor is still a distant dream. Microfinance has succeeded in making a dent in poverty in a number of developing countries. The few innovations in India, though sporadic, have also proved that microfinance can be a potent tool to tackle poverty. There is an urgent need to upscale these innovations. Notwithstanding the progress made over the decades, majority of the rural population still does not appear to have access to finance from a formal source, according to the Rural Financial Access Survey (RFAS) 2003. Some 59 per cent of rural households do not have a deposit account and 79 per cent of rural households have no access to credit from a formal source. The problem of access is even more severe for poorer households in rural areas. Indeed, bank branches in rural areas appear to serve primarily the needs of richer borrowers. Some 66 per cent of large farmers have a deposit account; 44 per cent have access to credit, meanwhile, 70 per cent of marginal farmers do not have a bank account and 87 per cent have no access to credit from a formal source. Presently, the microfinance scenario needs to be reviewed for emerging trends, concerns and growth prospect. The question that how best this Micro finance programme has been really benefiting the beneficiaries still remains to be examined. The present study under reference is one such an attempt to asses the performance of the SHG network of the microfinancing programme in terms of its generation of income and employment of the beneficiaries in the sample district in Andhra Pradesh state.

Alexander Decker

2020, IAEME PUBLICATION
While microfinance becomes an acute poverty alleviation mechanism in most of the developing countries, the sustainability of its approaches also becoming crucial with the passes of time and to restore sustainability of microfinance members in the district, the problems with members need to be minimized at the earliest. The aim of this paper is to identify the problems with microfinance services in the district and reveal some way-out. The study is based on both primary and secondary data, but mainly focused on primary data, which have been collected using schedule to attain the objective. The study reveal that, members are suffering from many problems, like delays in disbursement of loans, trainings, insufficient amount of credit, small slabs of loans, problems with maintenance of books of accounts, unsatisfactory income, lack of cooperation among the members etc. Further problems with ‘micro-credit’ is found as the mostly cited problems with sustainability in the district, followed by problems of group management.


IMAGES
VIDEO
COMMENTS
It is expected to play a significant role in poverty alleviation and development.The emphasis of present paper is to study the performance and role of microfinance institutions in the...
on 12th July 2002 pm Atal Bihari Vajpayee outlined an eight-point agenda to push the economy on a growth path of 8% during the 10th plan microfinance is being practiced as a tool to attack poverty. the world over the growth of micro finance is visible in many aspects. there are more than 2000 no involved in the NABARD shg bank linkage programme ...
4 CrossRef citations to date 0 Altmetric Listen FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Ownership and performance of microfinance institutions: Empirical evidences from India Asif Khan , Alam Ahmad & Saba Shireen | David McMillan (Reviewing editor) Article: 1930653 | Received 12 Jul 2020, Accepted 09 May 2021, Published online: 02 Jun 2021 Cite this article
This includes 95 published research articles on microfinance. These articles are identified through a systematic search of electronic databases by focusing on the major keywords microfinance,...
Abbreviations 8India Microffnance Review FY 2020-21 About this Report The microfinance sector in India perhaps receives more than its fair share of analysis and coverage.
SUBMIT PAPER. Vision: The Journal of Business Perspective. Impact Factor: 2.8 / 5-Year Impact Factor: ... Microfinance Research in India During 2001-2021: A Bibliometric Analysis with Its Social Impact Using Altmetrics ... & Bapat V. (2015). Sustainability index of micro finance institutions (MFIs) and contributory factors. International ...
This paper empirically examines whether competition (measured by using the new measure of competition, the Boone Indicator) moderates the relationship between Microfinance Institutions' (MFIs) social and financial performances using data from 183 Indian MFIs over the period 2005-2014. The findings indicate that MFIs' social and financial performances have a positive significant relationship.
This background paper was prepared for the report Asian Development Outlook 2021: Financing a Green and ... as evidenced by the existence of 916 microfinance institutions (MFIs) with an approximate aggregate loan portfolio of $124 billion. MFIs had 140 ... levels and improve living standards" by the Reserve Bank of India (2000, p. 1). Yet ...
The present paper aims at identifying the current status and role of microfinance in the development of India. Keywords: Microfinance; SHGs, MFIs; Status and Growth of Microfinance Suggested Citation: Saini, Ms Neha and Kumar, Bhupendra and Pathak, O. P., A Conceptual Study of Micro Finance in India (November 10, 2017).
(2015), Microfinance: Strong Comeback Microfinance Institutions Indian rating and research, A Fitch group company, January 2015. Microfinance India, State of the Sector Report Jan 2013
As part of its policy advocacy efforts, MFIN Board has commissioned this paper to map the present and potential economic impact NBFC-MFIs and the microfinance sector may create in the foreseeable future and therefore, play a vital role in achievement of the financial inclusion in the country.
Microfinance in India: Issues, Challenges and Opportunities Authors: Mohammad Abu Saleh Veer Bahadur Singh Purvanchal University Zubair Ahmad The purpose of the paper is to highlight the...
James Copestake University of Bath Abstract and Figures Microfinance (MF) has grown over the last two decades into an important sub-field of development studies. This special issue of Oxford...
Vivek Tripathi School of Management Studies MNNIT ALLAHABAD -211004 Vineet Tripathi Deemed Universities of India Date Written: July 3, 2014 Abstract With 1.2 billion people and the world's fourth - largest economy, India's recent growth and development has been one of the most significant achievements of our times.
microfinance providers and varied microlending models. As part of our research on the microfinance industry in India, we conducted two surveys during September-October 2019, designed to understand the issues and challenges faced by the microfinance industry and gain insights into the expectations of the industry. One
MFI (Micro Finance In India) is play very important role in development. Microfinance is a very important source of financial services for people and microenterprises that do not have easy...
Microfinance can be researched narrowly as an instrument for promoting development or more broadly as an endogenous component of development. This paper sets out a simple well-being regime model ...
This research paper involves study of the past literatures about the microfinance sector, related online research papers and journals. ... /journal/IJMHRM 91 [email protected] A Study on the Trend and Growth of Microfinance Institutions in India Table-6 Assets with MFIs over the years Year Assets 2015 22736 2016 24240 2017 28051 2018 36125 2019 ...
(Radhakrishna, 2012) In this research paper the researcher talks about the rapid growth in the expansion of MFIs in India and how there is a change in the functioning of MFIs which has turned into accelerating the improvements in governance, responsible finance practices and regulatory capacity.
Manisha Raj [8], in his research paper entitled condition of microfinance institutions in India. The "Microfinance Institutions in India and its Legal Aspects" research paper also tells why the microfinance institutions states that Microfinance institutions have been proved a charges high interest to the borrowers. Here, in this
In India it began in the 1980s with the formation of pockets of informal Self Help Groups (SHG) engaging in micro activities financed by Microfinance. But India's first Microfinance Institution ...
A Study on Microfinance in India by parveen kumar — Microfinance is a source of fi nance to the poor segments of society. It i ncludes loans, savi ngs, credit, insurance services, money transfer and other basic financial services to the economically weaker section of society.
Challenges faced by Micro finance There are over 10,000 microfinance institutions serving in excess of 150m customers, 100m of them being the poorest families. Microfinance is gathering momentum to become a significant force in India. Some challenges faced by micro finance in India are: